diff --git "a/data/CHRG-110/CHRG-110hhrg33655.txt" "b/data/CHRG-110/CHRG-110hhrg33655.txt" new file mode 100644--- /dev/null +++ "b/data/CHRG-110/CHRG-110hhrg33655.txt" @@ -0,0 +1,4095 @@ + +
+[House Hearing, 110 Congress] +[From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] + + + + + ARE HIDDEN 401(K) FEES + UNDERMINING RETIREMENT SECURITY? +======================================================================= + + + + HEARING + + before the + + COMMITTEE ON + EDUCATION AND LABOR + + U.S. House of Representatives + + ONE HUNDRED TENTH CONGRESS + + FIRST SESSION + + __________ + + HEARING HELD IN WASHINGTON, DC, MARCH 6, 2007 + + __________ + + Serial No. 110-7 + + __________ + + Printed for the use of the Committee on Education and Labor + + + Available on the Internet: + http://www.gpoaccess.gov/congress/house/education/index.html + + + + + U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE +33-655 PDF WASHINGTON : 2007 +--------------------------------------------------------------------- +For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government +Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) +512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202)512-2250 Mail: Stop SSOP, +Washington, DC 20402-0001 + + + + COMMITTEE ON EDUCATION AND LABOR + + GEORGE MILLER, California, Chairman + +Dale E. Kildee, Michigan, Vice Howard P. ``Buck'' McKeon, + Chairman California, +Donald M. Payne, New Jersey Ranking Minority Member +Robert E. Andrews, New Jersey Thomas E. Petri, Wisconsin +Robert C. ``Bobby'' Scott, Virginia Peter Hoekstra, Michigan +Lynn C. Woolsey, California Michael N. Castle, Delaware +Ruben Hinojosa, Texas Mark E. Souder, Indiana +Carolyn McCarthy, New York Vernon J. Ehlers, Michigan +John F. Tierney, Massachusetts Judy Biggert, Illinois +Dennis J. Kucinich, Ohio Todd Russell Platts, Pennsylvania +David Wu, Oregon Ric Keller, Florida +Rush D. Holt, New Jersey Joe Wilson, South Carolina +Susan A. Davis, California John Kline, Minnesota +Danny K. Davis, Illinois Bob Inglis, South Carolina +Raul M. Grijalva, Arizona Cathy McMorris Rodgers, Washington +Timothy H. Bishop, New York Kenny Marchant, Texas +Linda T. Sanchez, California Tom Price, Georgia +John P. Sarbanes, Maryland Luis G. Fortuno, Puerto Rico +Joe Sestak, Pennsylvania Charles W. Boustany, Jr., +David Loebsack, Iowa Louisiana +Mazie Hirono, Hawaii Virginia Foxx, North Carolina +Jason Altmire, Pennsylvania John R. ``Randy'' Kuhl, Jr., New +John A. Yarmuth, Kentucky York +Phil Hare, Illinois Rob Bishop, Utah +Yvette D. Clarke, New York David Davis, Tennessee +Joe Courtney, Connecticut Timothy Walberg, Michigan +Carol Shea-Porter, New Hampshire + + Mark Zuckerman, Staff Director + Vic Klatt, Minority Staff Director + + + C O N T E N T S + + ---------- + Page + +Hearing held on March 6, 2007.................................... 1 +Statement of Members: + Altmire, Hon. Jason, a Representative in Congress from the + State of Pennsylvania, prepared statement of............... 60 + Hare, Hon. Phil, a Representative in Congress from the State + of Illinois, prepared statement of......................... 60 + McKeon, Hon. Howard P. ``Buck,'' Senior Republican Member, + Committee on Education and Labor........................... 4 + Prepared statement of.................................... 5 + Miller, Hon. George, Chairman, Committee on Education and + Labor...................................................... 1 + +Statement of Witnesses: + Bovbjerg, Barbara D., Director, Health, Education, Human + Services Division, Government Accountability Office........ 7 + Internet link to GAO-prepared testimony, ``Private + Pensions: Increased Reliance on 401(k) Plans Calls for + Better Information on Fees''........................... 9 + Butler, Stephen J., president and founder, Pension Dynamics + Corp....................................................... 28 + Prepared statement of.................................... 30 + Chambers, Robert, Esq., partner, Helms, Mulliss & Wicker, + PLLC; chairman, American Benefits Council.................. 22 + Prepared statement of.................................... 24 + Hutcheson, Matthew, pension consultant, independent pension + fiduciary.................................................. 9 + Prepared statement of.................................... 10 + + + ARE HIDDEN 401(K) FEES + UNDERMINING RETIREMENT SECURITY? + + ---------- + + + Tuesday, March 6, 2007 + + U.S. House of Representatives + + Committee on Education and Labor + + Washington, DC + + ---------- + + The committee met, pursuant to call, at 11:02 a.m., in room +2175, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. George Miller +[chairman of the committee] presiding. + Present: Representatives Miller, Kildee, Payne, Andrews, +Woolsey, McCarthy, Tierney, Wu, Davis of California, Sestak, +Yarmuth, Hare, Courtney, Shea-Porter, McKeon, Petri, Ehlers, +Kline, Marchant, Fortuno, Boustany, Davis of Tennessee, and +Walberg. + Staff present: Aaron Albright, Press Secretary; Tylease +Alli, Hearing Clerk; Jody Calemine, Labor Policy Deputy +Director; Sarah Dyson, Administrative Assistant, Oversight; +Carlos Fenwick, Policy Advisor for Subcommittee on Health, +Employment, Labor and Pensions; Michael Gaffin, Staff +Assistant, Labor; Jeffrey Hancuff, Staff Assistant, Labor; Ryan +Holden, Senior Investigator, Oversight; Brian Kennedy, General +Counsel; Thomas Kiley, Communications Director; Ann-Frances +Lambert, Administrative Assistant to Director of Education +Policy; Danielle Lee, Press/Outreach Assistant; Joe Novotny, +Chief Clerk; Megan O'Reilly, Labor Policy Advisor; Rachel +Racusen, Deputy Communications Director; Michele Varnhagen, +Labor Policy Director; Michael Zola, Chief Investigative +Counsel, Oversight; Mark Zuckerman, Staff Director; Robert +Borden, General Counsel; Steve Forde, Communications Director; +Ed Gilroy, Director of Workforce Policy; Rob Gregg, Legislative +Assistant; Jessica Gross, Deputy Press Secretary; Taylor +Hansen, Legislative Assistant; Victor Klatt, Staff Director; +Lindsey Mask, Director of Outreach; Jim Paretti, Workforce +Policy Counsel; Molly McLaughlin Salmi, Deputy Director of +Workforce Policy; and Linda Stevens, Chief Clerk/Assistant to +the General Counsel. + Chairman Miller [presiding]. The Committee on Education and +Labor will come to order for the purposes of conducting a +hearing of whether or not hidden 401(k) fees are undermining +workers' retirement security. + This is, again, one of a series of hearings where we are +looking at the middle class and what we can do to strengthen +and to cultivate the middle class. + And I think that this is a very important hearing, because +it does deal with the ability of millions of middle-class +workers, whether or not they will have the ability to put +together a plan for retirement security and for the maintenance +of a standard of living that allows them to provide for +themselves and their families. + If you earn your income from a paycheck, the chances are +that one of the things you are concerned with is trying to put +enough money away for the golden years. If you use a 401(k) or +a similar plan to help you save some of that money for +retirement, then you ought to have all of the information you +need to make a well-informed decision about what plans and +investment options will give you the best deal. + That is the purpose of this hearing: to examine the growing +role of 401(k)-style plans are playing in helping people pay +for their retirement and find out if hidden fees are eating +into workers' retirement savings account balances without them +even knowing it. + During much of the 20th century, two types of retirement +plans--Social Security and traditional employment-based pension +plans--helped to lift older Americans out of poverty and +allowed American workers to maintain a decent standard of +living when their working lives were over. + But now today, many of those traditional pensions, defined +benefit plans, are no longer being created. New plans are being +created or greater reliance is being placed on 401(k) plans, +and clearly Social Security is now the sole source of +retirement income for over half of the retirees and the primary +source of income for two-thirds of all retirees. + Luckily, I would say, we have fended off the attacks on the +program from people who wanted to privatize it, turning it into +a gamble for retirees, instead of a sure thing. So we now have +Social Security and 401(k)s. + The rub is that 401(k)s were never intended to be the +primary source of retirement income, either. Today, the average +balance among private-sector workers is just $28,000, and that +is a pool of workers that struggle at the end of every month to +be able to continue to invest in their retirement savings and +in their ultimate retirement. + This morning, we will hear testimony about services that +are being provided and the fees are being charged. Some of +these fees are reasonable and necessary, but today we will also +hear about a dizzying array of terminology, revenue-sharing, +and wrap fees, finders' fees, shelf space, surrender charges, +soft dollars, 12(b)(1) fees. + We have to ask whether or not all of these fees are +necessary, and we have to examine whether they are undermining +the workers retirement security. That is because even a +seemingly small difference in the fees that workers pay can +have an enormous difference in the overall size of their 401(k) +balance. + As we will hear later today, a 1 percentage point +difference in fees can reduce retirement benefits by nearly 20 +percent. So you have a situation where people are struggling to +put this money away every month, and making the sacrifices that +go along with that, and yet we see just that 1 percentage +difference. + As a way of an example, if you take one person +participating in the Thrift Savings Plan, where people who are +making the same contribution over a 30-year period of time, and +the other is going into an asset-based fees program, what you +see here is that at the end of that time, the amount available +is $175,000, if you had an asset-based fees or 3 percent, and +$279,000, as you have in the Thrift Savings Plan. + Three hundred basis points is not unusual, I am told, but +as we will hear that from the experts, it creates dramatic +difference in what people can expect to draw on and how long +they will expect these funds to last. And so this kind of +difference insists that we pay attention to this matter. + Over the years, I have participated in a number of +conferences on savings plans, on getting America to save more. +How do we encourage savers to do this? With tax deductions, and +tax credits, and all the rest of it, and those are all very, +very important. + But if, in fact, what we see is, after workers with very +limited resources make the very difficult decision to save +their money,, the question is, what is the stewardship of that +money? + We understand the laws of the fiduciary relationship and +the responsibilities of trust to those individuals. But the +fact of the matter is, it does not appear that that is always +being honored. + The other thing here is that sometimes when people, delve +into this subject, it is very complicated, as you will start to +hear when the witnesses start to speak about it. Most of these +explanations are not written in plain English. Most of these +explanations are not presented in a matter in which +participants can understand them. + If you go through this information packet for these fees, I +am sure that either your head will be on your chest, your eyes +will be glazed over, and you simply will not be able to +decipher the information that you need as the saver. + Now, people will argue that this is for the plans, that the +plans can look at this and make these determinations. The +language is complicated; the language in many cases is +unintelligible; the choices are unknown to the participant at +many levels. + And so what we have is a situation where people work very +hard, make the decision we want them to make, to set aside +money for their retirement, and what they find out is there is +a lot of people who are putting their hands into that money in +the names of fees, commissions, all of the terms that I used +before. + And what happens at the end of the year, what happens at +the end of 10 years and 20 years and 30 years is that a +remarkable amount of the assets that could have been available +for retirement have leaked out of that fund to the benefit of +others. + We will remember through the course of this hearing and of +future hearings, the only source for all of the fees and the +commissions is the hard-earned retirement dollars that these +people have set aside and that their employers have contributed +to, in some cases. All of the fees, all of the commissions are +derived from that source of money. + And that is what makes, I believe, this hearing so +critical, on what we might do, what we should consider, in +terms of further disclosure, and further transparency, and +certainly to make it more understandable for middle-class +families, as they consider the choices that they have to build +that retirement nest egg, using the 401(k) plan. + So I look forward to hearing the witnesses. + And at this time, I would like to recognize Mr. McKeon, the +senior Republican on the committee, and then I will--hope +springs---- + [Laughter.] + I don't want you to characterize the hope I have. It is +truly mine. But at that time, then I will introduce the +witnesses. + Mr. McKeon? + Mr. McKeon. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thanks for the +reprieve. + As you know, this committee is no stranger to the issue of +retirement security. And in fact, I would say we have proven +ourselves the House's leader on this important issue. + In the long term, I believe the pension legislation we +enacted last year will prove to be one of the most meaningful +reforms of the 109th Congress. And the fact that we were able +to do it in a bipartisan way, with 76 Democrats supporting the +bill, and in an election year, no less, demonstrated what a +bottom-line issue this is to workers, retirees and taxpayers. + We should not forget that those pension reforms were set in +motion right there in this committee room. And though we did +not have universal agreement at the end of the process or even +as little as a comprehensive alternative plan from the other +side of the aisle, we did produce what has become the most +fundamental overhaul of the private pension system in more than +a generation. + Indeed, the ground work for today's hearing and those that +may follow has clearly and concretely been laid by our previous +work. The issue before us is one that has become increasingly +important, because defined contribution plans are clearly the +future of our retirement security system. + In fact, in addition to the new safeguards we put in place +last year to bolster the traditional defined benefits system, I +believe two of the most important aspects of our pension reform +bill focused on 401(k) plans. + First, we established new auto-enrollment procedures to +increase the number of 401(k) participants. And, secondly, we +fixed a flaw in outdated pension law that barred workers from +receiving high-quality, independent investment advice as an +employee benefit. + Years from now, I believe we will look back upon these +reforms as a starting point or a turning point, placing more +power than even before in the hands of workers, as they make +decisions about their retirement. + This morning, as we look at potentially tweaking 401(k) +rules, I will say what I said during the pension reform debate +from the last Congress: Our first principle must be to do no +harm. The pension bill we passed last year took years to get +ready for the president's signature, and for good reason. We +did not want to do anything that would force employers out of +this voluntary system, nor did we want to take any action that +would have discouraged retirement savings or investment, +unintended consequences that we fought vigorously to avoid. + This should be guiding philosophy once again this time +around. For example, if we are considering whether to place +additional requirements upon plan sponsors on top of those we +already established a year ago, we must do so with great +caution, as the financial futures of millions of workers and +retirees depend upon it. + At the outset of this hearing process, I also believe that +it is vital to understand the delicate balance that exists +within our retirement security system. For instance, workers do +have a responsibility to make certain decisions involving their +savings. Likewise, I believe we all must recognize that the +topic of today's hearings, the 401(k) fees, are one of many +factors, such as the historical performance and investment risk +for each plan option, which plan participants do have +responsibility to consider when investing in a 401(k) plan. + Now, do we want to or expect workers to be completely on +their own? Of course not. No one believes that. But at the same +time, we must resist the urge to simply overload workers with +information. That little prospectus that you held up a while +ago, one of the reasons that that is so thick and cumbersome is +regulations and laws that we have passed here. + We must not mandate the distribution of out-of-context +information that may lead participants to poor investment +choices. A quick fix like that may help some of us feel good +about ourselves, but it would do great harm to workers and +retirees, which as I said is what we must seek to avoid. + Mr. Chairman, I believe our time together today will serve +to start the process of deliberately and thoughtfully examining +whether changes to federal law are necessary to provide greater +information to plan participants. I enter it with an open mind, +just as I am sure you and all of our colleagues do. + I appreciate our witnesses taking the time to be with us +today, and I look forward to their testimony. + Thank you. + [The prepared statement of Mr. McKeon follows:] + +Prepared Statement of Hon. Howard P. ``Buck'' McKeon, Senior Republican + Member, Committee on Education and Labor + + Chairman Miller, as you know, this Committee is no stranger to the +issue of retirement security, and in fact, I'd say we have proven +ourselves the House's leader on this important issue. In the long-term, +I believe the pension legislation we enacted last year will prove to be +the most meaningful reforms of the 109th Congress. And the fact that we +were able to do it in a bipartisan way--with 76 Democrats supporting +the bill, and in an election year, no less--demonstrated what a bottom +line issue this is to workers, retirees, and taxpayers. + We should not forget that those pension reforms were set in motion +right here, in this Committee room, and though we did not have +universal agreement at the end of the process--or even as little as a +comprehensive alternative plan from the other side of the aisle--we did +produce what has become the most fundamental overhaul of the private +pension system in more than a generation. Indeed, the groundwork for +today's hearing and those that may follow has clearly and concretely +been laid by our previous work. + The issue before us is one that has become increasingly important +because defined contribution plans are clearly the future of our +retirement security system. In fact, in addition to the new safeguards +we put in place last year to bolster the traditional defined benefit +system, I believe two of the most important aspects of our pension +reform bill focused on 401(k) plans. + First, we established new auto-enrollment procedures to increase +the number of 401(k) participants, and secondly, we fixed a flaw in +outdated pension law that barred workers from receiving high-quality, +independent investment advice as an employee benefit. Years from now, I +believe we will look back upon these reforms as a turning point, +placing more power than ever before into the hands of workers as they +make decisions about their retirement. + This morning, as we look at potentially tweaking 401(k) rules, I +will say what I said during the pension reform debate from the last +Congress: our first principle must be to do no harm. The pension bill +we passed last year took years to get ready for the President's +signature, and for good reason. We did not want to do anything that +would force employers out of this voluntary system, nor did we want to +take any action that would have discouraged retirement savings or +investment--unintended consequences that we fought vigorously to avoid. + This should be our guiding philosophy once again this time around. +For example, if we are considering whether to place additional +requirements upon plan sponsors--on top of those we already established +a year ago--we must do so with great caution, as the financial futures +of millions of workers and retirees depend upon it. + At the outset of this hearing process, I also believe that it is +vital to understand the delicate balance that exists within our +retirement security system. For instance, workers do have a +responsibility to make certain decisions involving their savings. +Likewise, I believe we all must recognize that the topic of today's +hearing--401(k) fees--are one of many factors, such as the historical +performance and investment risk for each plan option, which plan +participants do have the responsibility to consider when investing in a +401(k) plan. + Now, do we want to--or expect--workers to be completely on their +own? Of course not; no one believes that. But at the same time, we must +resist the urge to simply overload workers with information--or worse, +to mandate the distribution of out-of-context information that may lead +participants to make poor investment choices. A quick fix like that may +help some of us feel good about ourselves, but it would do great harm +to workers and retirees, which--as I said--is what we must seek to +avoid. + Mr. Chairman, I believe our time together today will serve to start +the process of deliberately and thoughtfully examining whether changes +to federal law are necessary to provide greater information to plan +participants. I enter it with an open mind, just as I am sure you and +all of our colleagues do. I appreciate our witnesses taking the time to +be with us today, and I look forward to their testimony. + ______ + + Chairman Miller. Thank you. + Our panel this morning is a distinguished panel with a long +history in this subject. + And first witness will be Barbara D. Bovbjerg, who is the +director of education, workforce and income security issues at +the U.S. Government Accountability Office. At the GAO, she +oversees evaluative studies on age and retirement income policy +issues, including Social Security, private pension programs, +and the operation and managements at the Social Security +Administration, the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation, the +Employee Benefits Security Administration of the Department of +Labor. + Matthew D. Hutcheson is an independent pension fiduciary. +He is the author of a text, ``Retirement Plan Compliance and +Reporting,'' at Texas Tech University's International +Foundation for Retirement Education. He is also a member of the +Board of Standards at the American Academy of Financial +Management. His clients include the plans of Fortune 100, 500 +and 1,000 companies, mid-and small-size companies, government +and legal and accounting firms. + Mr. Robert Chambers is a partner in the Employer Services +Practice Group, of the Charlotte-based law firm of Helms, +Mulliss & Wicker. And his practice emphasizes executive +compensation and employee benefit law. Mr. Chambers is a member +of the taxation, business and law, and employment law sections +of the American Bar Association and serves on several +committees within those sections. He is the chairman of the +American Benefits Council, an employee-benefit lobbying firm in +Washington, whose members either employ or administer plans for +more than 100 Americans, and a 1971 graduate of Princeton +University. + Mr. Stephen J. Butler is the founder and president of the +Pension Dynamics Corporation retirement plan administration +firm in Pleasant Hill, California. In April 1997, Money +magazine published Mr. Butler's article entitled, ``Beware: +Retirement Plan Rip-offs.'' Mr. Butler has also written two +books on 401(k) plans, the most recent being one titled +``401(k) Today,'' published in 1999. For the past 7 years, he +has been a weekly columnist covering retirement-related +financial interests and has been quoted extensively in Fortune +and Money, the Wall Street Journal, New York Times and numerous +other publications. + So, Ms. Bovbjerg, we will begin with you. + And you know the rules here, but for the other witnesses, +the green light will be on for 5 minutes, then it will turn to +orange, which we will ask you to start summing in, and then +red, if you can wrap your remarks so that we will have time for +questions. + Thank you. + +STATEMENT OF BARBARA D. BOVBJERG, DIRECTOR, HEALTH, EDUCATION, + HUMAN SERVICES DIVISION, GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE + + Ms. Bovbjerg. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Mr. McKeon, members +of the committee. + I am pleased to be here today to speak about 401(k) plans. +And in these plans, participating workers are responsible for +choosing how much of their earnings to contribute, how to +invest these contributions, and how to manage the resultant +accumulation in retirement. + Today, I would like to describe trends in the use of +401(k)s and summarize our recent report about fees associated +with these plans. Fees are one of the aspects of 401(k)s that +workers should know about and understand in order to ensure +adequate income from the plan when they retire. + First, the trends. 401(k)s are defined contribution, D.C., +plans, meaning that benefits are based on contributions to +accounts and investment returns that accrue. Historically, +pension benefits were provided through defined benefit, D.B., +plans, which provide a fixed level of monthly retirement income +for life, based on salary, service and age of retirement. + Since 1985, the number of D.C. plans and participants has +risen dramatically, while the number of D.B. plans and workers +covered by them has fallen. Today, there are about 700,000 D.C. +plans, covering 55 million workers, and D.C. plans now hold the +majority of pension fund assets. + 401(k) plans are an important part of this gross. Although +they were once relatively rare, today they predominate among +D.C.-type plans. In 1985, they were only about 7 percent of all +D.C. plans, but now account for almost 95 percent. In 20 years, +the number of participants in these plans has grown from 7 +million to 47 million workers, and assets held by these plans +rose from $270 billion to about $2.5 trillion. + 401(k) plans are popular with many workers, in that they +are portable, which D.B.'s are generally not, and they are +easier to understand than typical D.B. plans. Yet 401(k)s also +place responsibilities on workers that D.B. plans do not. + The majority of 401(k) plans are participant-directed. +Because so much rides of workers' decisions with regard to +their 401(k) saving, it is crucial that workers have +information to help them make wise choices. + There are many factors that a worker should take into +account, one being the fees associated with the plan. So let me +turn now to issues regarding fees. + Fees are important factors in 401(k)s because, in general, +the higher the fee, the less savings will accumulate in the +course of a working lifetime. Although various fees pertain to +401(k)s, investment fees account for the largest portion of the +total. These pay for services including selecting the plan's +portfolio of securities and managing the fund. + Plan record-keeping fees are the next largest. These are +usually charged by the service provider to set up and maintain +the plan. Whether and how participants or plan sponsors pay +these fees varies by the type of fee and the size of the plan. + Investment fees are usually charged at the 6 percentage of +assets and netted from investment return, while record-keeping +fees may be charged as a percentage of assets, or as flat fees. +These fees are increasingly being paid by participants, rather +than by sponsors. ERISA requires that sponsors disclose a range +of information about plans, but only limited information about +fees. + Although plan sponsors may voluntarily provide information +on fees, participants may not have a clear picture of all the +fees they pay, because even the information that is provided +may be offered in a piecemeal fashion, through plan +descriptions, fund prospectuses, and fund profiles. + Not only do participants not necessarily know what they are +paying in fees overall, they have no simple way to compare fees +among investment options within their plan. The Department of +Labor has authority under ERISA to oversee 401(k) fees and fee +arrangements among plan service providers, but it lacks +information sufficient to provide effective oversight. + Labor must ensure that fees are paid with plan assets, are +reasonable, and that sponsors report information known about +business arrangements involving service providers. But it is +difficult for Labor to monitor fees that are netted out of +returns and are not required to be reporter. Further, fee +arrangements between service providers are sometimes hidden +from the sponsor and can mask a conflict of interest that could +affect the plan. + Labor has initiatives under way to improve the disclosure +of fee information to participants, as well as in required +reporting to Labor itself, and to spell out what information +sponsors need to obtain from service providers. + In conclusion, 401(k) have emerged as the primary type of +pension plans for American workers, yet requirements for +reporting information workers should have to manage these types +of plans has not fully caught up to the need. Fee information, +in particular, needs to be more widely available, more +comprehensive, and more clearly presented. + GAO has recommended that measures be taken by both Labor +and the Congress to help make this information more accessible +and, in so doing, help protect workers' retirement savings. + This concludes my statement, Mr. Chairman. I welcome any +questions and hope that my full statement will be included in +the record. + [The Internet link to GAO-prepared testimony, ``Private +Pensions: Increased Reliance on 401(k) Plans Calls for Better +Information on Fees'' follows:] + + http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d07530t.pdf + ------ + + Chairman Miller. Thank you. + For all the witnesses, your statement, all your written +material will be put in the record in its entirety. + Mr. Hutcheson? + +STATEMENT OF MATTHEW HUTCHESON, PENSION CONSULTANT, INDEPENDENT + PENSION FIDUCIARY + + Mr. Hutcheson. Chairman Miller, Congressman McKeon and +members of the committee, from personal experience and research +as an independent fiduciary, I believe the retirement income of +America's workforce has been unnecessarily reduced due to +confusion caused by blending fiduciary and non-fiduciary +practices. + Many billions more should be available for health care and +prescription drugs, home repairs, and basic living necessities. +Instead, these sums line the pockets of others. + Conventional 401(k) plans now cost around 3 percent of plan +assets per year to manage. Some are even as high as 5 percent. +In my experience, that is 1.5 to 3.5 percent more than is +reasonably necessary. + To put this into perspective, just 1 percent in excess +costs to plan participants, having $2.5 trillion in 401(k) plan +assets, represents a wealth transfer of $25 billion to others +each and every year. A large portion of the costs of +conventional 401(k) plans relate to services that have little +or nothing to do with building and protecting the retirement +income security and, hence, are excessive. + Take an average participant with a $30,000 account balance, +contributing $150 per pay period. If this person earns an +average of 8 percent over a 25-year time period, he or she will +have accumulated over $500,000. However, add an additional 1 +percent in annual fees, and the account balance drops nearly +$85,000. Add 1 percent more, and the account balance drops +$150,000. + This translates into approximately $540 per month in +retirement income loss. This loss can be prevented, and it +begins by enlightening plan sponsors about the realities of +401(k) plan economics. When we buy bread, we know exactly how +much it costs: One dollar buys one dollar's worth of bread. +However, when it comes to 401(k) plans, the sticker price is +advertised at 50 cents, yet the actual cost may be closer to +three dollars. + Fiduciaries simply cannot make good decisions when the +costs of services are undisclosed. There are at least seven +types of hidden fees or costs borne by plan participants. These +range from brokerage fees, shared between the broker and an +investment fund, to record-keeping subsidies between a mutual +fund a third-party administrator. + Contrary to fiduciary principles, some of the fees borne by +participants are for services they do not receive. It is costly +and unnecessary to offer a wider variety of investment +alternatives than is absolutely necessary to construct a +prudent, low-cost portfolio. + The more fund choice is offered, the more mistakes +participants make. Employees tinker with the investment within +their accounts, incurring hidden trading costs that reduce +their returns. + The current 401(k) environment encourages mistakes, for no +good or necessary reason. The brokerage and investment fund +industries understand and count on participants making +imprudent investment decisions. They rely on fiduciary +ignorance to generate revenue. This is a substantial and hidden +cost about which participants are almost universally unaware. + An efficient, low-cost, market-tracking portfolio could +easily and fairly be put in place for all participants. To my +astonishment, the industry persists in the assertion that, +without higher fees, they cannot deliver the desired services. + This is the heart of the matter: It is the services or plan +options that are excessive, and those services or options are +not always necessary for protecting participants' retirement +income. Because 401(k) participants own stocks and bonds, +constituting $2.5 trillion, it is essential that plans be +managed by individuals who understand and uphold the standards +of fiduciary care and loyalty. + In conclusion, it is incumbent upon us to be absolutely +certain there are no unnecessary obstacles, whether intentional +or unintentional, to the long-term success of our private +retirement system. American workers deserve proper protections +for the hard-earned savings they have set aside in their 401(k) +plans, but these protections have been largely denied in the +current state of the industry. + I believe in implementing simple solutions. Change will +require exposing and confronting powerful economic interests +that support the current system. It is daunting to tackle this +vital issue, affecting millions now and in generations to come. +Despite the forces arrayed against change, America's workers +deserve better than they have received to date from the +providers of 401(k) services. + Thank you. + [The statement of Mr. Hutcheson follows:] + + Prepared Statement of Matthew Hutcheson, Pension Consultant, + Independent Pension Fiduciary + +Introduction + Very few matters of social importance are more complex than the one +before you today. This particular issue is not only about uncovering +obscure dollars unscrupulously extracted from the account balances of +America's workforce, but it is also about correcting the culture that +has permitted the problem to thrive in the first place. This written +testimony will explain what the culture is, why it exists, how it has +evolved over time, how it violates basic economic principles, the +integrity of rules of fiduciary prudence, the exclusive benefit rule +under ERISA, and other common sense practices that are critical for +delivery of expected results from employer defined contribution +retirement plans. +The American Worker Is Hurt by What He Can't See + ``If we make a few rough calculations, the importance of the topic +will be very clear. The SEC estimates in Concept Release 33-8349, that +1% of the average mutual fund's investment return disappears each year +due to brokerage expense, execution costs, and transaction spreads. +Other industry sources indicate that an additional .50% slips away via +``revenue sharing payments.'' The impact on the average American is +profound. + ``Consider two thirty year old workers who each invest $3,000 +annually into their 401(k) programs. American #1's 401(k) program is +run according to stringent fiduciary principles and earns 7.5% +annually. However, American #2's 401(k) is operated by conflicted, +sales driven entities and only earns 6% annually after the +aforementioned return erosion. The table below details the results. + + + +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + American #1-- + Year Fiduciary 401(k) American #2--Hidden + Earning 7.5% Fee 401(k) Earning 6% +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +10................................................................ $45,624 $41,915 +20................................................................ $139,658 $116,978 +30................................................................ $333,463 $251,405 +40................................................................ $732,902 $492,143 +47................................................................ $1,244,260 $766,694 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + ``Even though both employees contributed the same amount and took +the same investment risk, American #2 must work an additional seven +years to make up for the lack of fiduciary oversight in his 401(k) +plan.''\1\ + The difference in hidden fees costs American worker #2 nearly +$500,000 during the illustrated period of time. This issue is about +real people, real money, and the quality of their lives later in life. +Consider the impact on American worker #2's ability to pay for health +care, prescription drugs, home repairs or even groceries. If actuarial +tables hold true, today's retiree may need to be prepared to live a +quarter century longer than his grandparents did. +Background +A ``401(k)'' is a Qualified Retirement Plan + Qualified retirement plan assets pursuant to Internal Revenue Code +(``IRC'') section 401(a) are held in trust pursuant to IRC Sec. 501(a ) +exclusively for the future benefits of participants and beneficiaries. +There are three types of ``qualified'' plans. +Stock bonus + Pension, and + Profit sharing + A 401(k) plan, as we call it, is actually a profit sharing plan (in +most cases) \2\ that has a feature allowing employees to take wages and +bonuses in cash, or defer them into the profit sharing plan, and hence +are often referred to as ``employee deferrals.'' However, those +employee deferrals are technically ``employer'' contributions made +pursuant to a ``cash or deferred election.'' Deposits of all employer +contributions, including employee deferrals, plus investment earnings +of ``401(k)'' plans are subject to the same rules of trust +administration, governance, and fiduciary prudence which apply to stock +bonus and traditional pension plans. +ERISA--Employee Retirement Income Security + The purpose of a retirement plan, including 401(k) plans, is to +provide future income for retired American workers. Those who are +charged with the management of a qualified retirement plan must do so +with an eye single to this purpose and none other. Such an individual +is a ``fiduciary.'' +Rules of Fiduciary Prudence + As it relates to the issue at hand, the following fiduciary axioms +have consistently held true: + Fiduciary based decisions secure future retirement income. + Non-fiduciary based decisions diminish future retirement +income. + Hidden and excessive fees exist because both types of +decisions (fiduciary based and non-fiduciary based) exist +simultaneously within 401(k) and other similar plans, complicating and +obscuring a fiduciary's ability to understand his duties and to +properly discharge them. + This written testimony will focus solely on 401(k) and similar plan +assets held in trust, pursuant to IRC Sec. 501(a). Therefore, rules of +Fiduciary Prudence are a fundamental component of this discussion +because trusts are governed and managed by fiduciaries. True prudent +practices should deliver optimal results. Poor or partial fiduciary +practices will deliver sub-optimal or even poor results. + Fiduciary principles and ideals are not obscure, nor are they +difficult to learn and understand. In fact, modern rules of fiduciary +prudence have existed for nearly two hundred years. However, in the +United States, the primary way fiduciary responsibilities are taught to +sponsors of retirement plans is through the financial industry. Since +an important element of fiduciary governance is monitoring those who +provide services to a retirement plan, strangely enough, we have +accepted a system where those being monitored are teaching those who +are doing the monitoring, and doing so according to their philosophies +and standards, with a particular objective in mind. + The current 401(k) culture essentially couples the ``fox teaching +the rooster how to guard the hen house'' with a perceived governmental +``get out of jail free card'' (i.e. DOL regulation 404(c)). The effect +of adopting these two ``cultural'' elements has, over time, caused +401(k) plans to be governed through the commingling of fiduciary and +non-fiduciary practices and philosophies. + Therefore, resolving the issue of hidden, obscure, and excessive +fees is wholly dependent on bifurcating fiduciary elements and +practices from the non-fiduciary ones within the 401(k) industry. Then, +logic will reveal that any fees paid for non-fiduciary services and +practices are unnecessary, and hence excessive. Furthermore, these are +the fees that are hidden because they simply cannot be justified when +viewed through the lens of true fiduciary prudence. In short, if +fiduciaries eliminate non-fiduciary practices in their 401(k) plans, +they will immediately eliminate hidden and excessive fees. To argue +otherwise would suggest that 401(k) plans are only ``partially'' +subject to fiduciary prudence, and hence are only a ``partially'' +qualified plan. + Conceptually, it is as simple as that--but in practice, it is far +more difficult. +Complexity + The hidden fee problem in 401(k) and similar plans is actually a +mysterious Gordian Knot consisting of trust law, tax law, public +policy, doctrines of fiduciary prudence, financial principle, economic +principle, and perhaps the lack of discipline to defer control and +gratification until actual retirement. It is difficult to see the ends +of the rope, and very few know how to unravel it. In addition, many who +might discern how to unravel it have strong incentives not to do so. + It is widely accepted that 401(k) and similar arrangements are the +way most Americans will invest for retirement. Therefore, it is +incumbent upon us all to be absolutely certain there are no unnecessary +obstacles (whether intentional or unintentional) to its long-term +success. As it stands today, there is an imbalance between prudent +practices aimed at efficiently securing the retirement income of +America's workforce, and non-fiduciary services created for business +purposes between competing service providers in the private sector. +Obstacles to a Clear Understanding + Conflicting Governmental messages that confuse +qualification rules under IRC Sec. 401(a) with rules of fiduciary +prudence and process as defined by Department of Labor regulation, case +law, and other regulatory pronouncements. + ``Exemptions'' given to non-fiduciary firms or individuals +to receive compensation from trust assets without being legally held to +a fiduciary standard of conduct. In other words, non-fiduciary +involvement in 401(k) plans has created a non-fiduciary operating +environment. + ERISA has imposed a federal fiduciary duty and +responsibility on business executives and board directors who serve as +``ERISA Fiduciaries'' requiring them to act exclusively in the best +interest of plan participants and beneficiaries. A growing chorus of +benefit industry gurus believes that such executives and directors had +a pre-existing fiduciary duty and responsibility to the owners of the +business. Query: Has ERISA unintentionally imposed an incurable +conflict of interest? That is, can any person faithfully serve the best +interest of two conflicting masters? Plan participants may believe they +are out of harm's way and protected, as fiduciary oversight is mandated +by ERISA, but increasingly these fiduciaries appear to be like a +sightless watchdog that doesn't bark. + Fiduciary ignorance, fear, uncertainty, and doubt, which +leads to non-fiduciary decisions and practices. +Identifying non-fiduciary practices, and their associated costs + Decisions and/or functions that are clearly fiduciary in nature +include proactively monitoring costs, selecting a proper number of +efficient investments necessary to construct an appropriate portfolio, +and operating the plan in exact accordance to its purpose--which is to +deliver retirement income to its beneficiaries. + Decisions and/or functions that are clearly imprudent include +purchasing high cost funds when their identical match is available at +perhaps less than half the cost, or turning a blind eye to obvious +mishandling of trust assets by non-fiduciaries (i.e. the participants) +and, at the same time, claiming for themselves protection from +fiduciary liability under 404(c). +Fiduciary/Non-fiduciary/``The Gray Area'' (Subject to discernment) + There are other decisions and/or functions that fall into a gray +area. Such decisions or functions might be prudent, or they might not +be. + The significance of this explanation is that some fees are +obviously necessary and prudent. Some fees are hidden and imprudent and +pay for excessive or unnecessary services. Finally, there are fees that +could be improper in some plans, and acceptable in others, and it takes +an experienced, discerning eye to recognize the differences. +Excessive is as excessive does + The following examples show the interplay between various +imprudent, hidden, and excessive fees as influenced by the 401(k) +culture described above. + Even at this time, a blatant non-fiduciary based feeding frenzy is +taking place at the expense of American workers' 401(k) plans. + ``The mutual fund industry is now the world's largest skimming +operation--a $7 trillion (now $12 trillion) trough from which fund +managers, brokers, and other insiders are steadily siphoning off an +excessive slice of the nation's household, college, and retirement +savings.'' \3\ ($12 trillion update added) + Most experts agree that trust fiduciary laws are nominally default +rules,\4\ and hence should be simple to adhere to and operate under. +However, managing 401(k) plans is anything but simple. It's a jumbled +mess because non-fiduciary investment sales people have infiltrated, +and now control what was intended to be a purely fiduciary function. + It would be simple to obtain optimal results. Then why isn't it +happening? + For example, the S&P 500 Index consistently outperformed 98% of +mutual fund managers over the past three years, 97% over the past 10 +years ending October 2004, and 94% over the past 30 years.\5\ + Recent studies reveal (and many more continue to substantiate), +that a passive 60% stock, 40% bond portfolio outperformed 90% of the +nation's largest corporate pension plan portfolios, ``run by the +world's best and brightest investment minds.'' \6\ The average return +on actively managed equity mutual funds over the past 35 years trails +the S&P by 87 basis points per year, and 105 basis points on broader +indexes. ``Over long periods, this difference in return amounted to +substantial differences in wealth.'' \7\ This is an unnecessary waste +of participant's hard earned money. ``This is why most academic and +many professional advisors recommend that the best investment strategy +is to match the market's performance. You can do this by putting your +money in a fund that holds all stocks in proportion to their market +value. Since these index funds do no research and little trading, the +costs of holding their portfolios are extremely small, some ranging as +low as 0.10 percent a year.'' \8\ + Then why do literally hundreds of thousands of 401(k) plan +fiduciaries do just the opposite? It's because they are ``guided'' to +particular decisions by non-fiduciaries (i.e. brokers, registered +representatives, insurance agents, etc.) in pursuit of compensation +which very frequently is in the form of hidden and excessive fees. +Making Sense of It All + Following are some of the usual hidden costs found in 401(k) plans. +Hidden Costs #1--Undisclosed Trading Costs + The assets held in account for the benefit of participants and +beneficiaries do not belong to them. These assets are owned by an +``entity,'' which is the trust. The participants are entitled to future +benefits from the trust. This is an important concept in trust +governance. In other words, if the investments belonged to the +participants right now, there would be no need for fiduciaries. +Therefore, the fiduciaries are charged with making decisions for the +future benefit of others, based on what they deem appropriate for the +participants and beneficiaries, in a similar way a member of the House +of Representatives makes decisions for their constituents. The decision +is based upon what they judge to be in their constituents' best +interests. + ``The new prudent investor rule directs the trustee to invest based +on risk and return objectives reasonably suited to the trust.'' \9\ + A major flaw in the 401(k) system, therefore, is allowing non- +fiduciaries (in this instance, plan participants themselves) to control +trust assets by choosing without skill from a large array of investment +choices, carefully presented in such a way as to generate additional +brokerage (trading) commissions by encouraging ``active'' trading +within participant accounts. In other words, emotional reactions of +participants who lack investment expertise trigger undisciplined and +imprudent investment decisions in the trust, when a simple 60/40 +portfolio described above is well within the reach of every single +participant. The brokerage and mutual fund industries not only fully +understand that participants are making imprudent investment decisions, +but are counting on participant ignorance to generate revenue. This is +a substantial and hidden cost that participants are almost universally +unaware, and have no concept of how it is reducing the future +retirement income they would otherwise receive. The average actively +traded mutual fund experiences approximately 80% turnover per year, +meaning that 80% of the underlying stocks and/or bonds are sold each +year. It is estimated that for every 1% in turnover, there is 1% in +added brokerage commission cost. Hence, the average mutual fund has an +added cost of .8% (otherwise known as 80 ``basis points.'') This is the +first hidden and unnecessary cost. + It becomes easier to understand why so many 401(k) plans primarily +offer (1) actively traded mutual funds, and (2) more funds than are +necessary to construct a prudent, low cost portfolio. It also +demonstrates rampant ignorance that exists in the fiduciary ranks--in +plans large and small. + ``TheStreet.com profiled a fund last year that had a 5 star rating, +a 1% expense ratio, and 800 bps in brokerage expense.''\10\ + Reducing net returns through unnecessary and excessive brokerage +expenses is a non-fiduciary and imprudent practice that runs counter to +the principles set forth in ERISA, which is to secure the retirement of +American workers. Consider the chaos that would result if Congress gave +each citizen 15 laws to choose from. Individually, we might pick and +choose those we deem appropriate for us and, in turn, adhere only to +the particular laws we chose. The principle of fiduciary prudence is +that fiduciaries make decisions for all individuals to whom they are +responsible based upon what is in their best interest, whether they +like it or not. As unpopular as this concept is, we must not equivocate +on protecting participants and beneficiaries from their own ignorance, +just as each of you protect your constituents from their ignorance on +various matters. + The current 401(k) culture has eroded the principles of true +fiduciary governance through the begging, pleading, lobbying, or +through other ways and means, we have drifted from ``protect and +nurture their needs'' to ``give them what they want--in fact, let's +give them even more than what they think they want.'' +Hidden Costs #2--SEC Rule 28(e) ``Soft Dollar'' Revenue Sharing + Hidden Cost #2 is symbiotic with Hidden Cost #1 above, and it +violates fundamental fiduciary rules and significantly hurts +participants. 28(e) Soft Dollars are generated by active trading within +mutual funds and similar investment vehicles. Allowing ``Soft Dollars'' +to go ``un-captured'' and credited back to the 401(k) trust is not a +fiduciary practice, and the historical problems caused by soft dollars +are self evident. + Shortly after the creation of the IRA, but before the creation of +the 401(k) as we know it, a change occurred within the brokerage and +mutual fund industry. As part of the Securities Acts Amendments of May +1975 (SAA '75), fixed commission rates on the purchase and sale of +securities through brokerage firms were eliminated. The significance of +the elimination of fixed commission rates would prove to be one of +several core issues of debate regarding fees in retirement plans. This +would ultimately allow brokerage firms to charge excess commissions, +thereby creating ``at play'' revenue that actually belonged to the +participants, which is commonly referred to as ``soft dollar'' revenue +or ``SEC Rule 28(e)'' revenue. With hundreds of billions of securities +trades each year, the revenue made available by SAA '75 would forever +change the mutual fund and retirement plan industry. These soft +dollars, coupled with the urgent need to compete in the 401(k) industry +and the creation of the 12(b)-1 in 1980 created the ``perfect fee +storm,'' which until now has existed with little or no notice by +Federal regulators, plan sponsors, participants, or the general public. + As a result of the Securities Acts Amendments of 1975, Section +28(e) was added to the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. With fixed +commission rates no longer the law, Section 28(e) created a safe harbor +for brokerage firms who exercise no investment discretion as defined +under Section 3(a)(35) of the 1934 Act to be able to charge a mutual +fund a commission that was more than what it costs to actually execute, +clear, and settle a securities transaction without violating the law or +fiduciary duties. This excess commission could be used to purchase +additional services from the brokerage firm in the form of presumably +valuable investment research. In order to receive protection under the +safe harbor, the mutual fund must act in good faith to ensure the +excess commission was ``reasonable in relation to the value of +brokerage and research services provided by the broker-dealer.'' Since +a passive indexing approach requires no research and also consistently +outperforms 90% of actively managed approaches that do require +research, then what is the value of the research? The 10% that do +outperform an indexing approach are temporarily fortuitous.\11\ If you +follow the money, modern investment research exists so 28(e) +commissions can be captured, not to provide consistent market returns +to participants. + Actively traded funds inherently have higher trading costs. In +other words, every time a mutual fund manager buys and/or sells the +underlying securities within the fund, the participants' return is +decreased by the cost of those trades. Part of the reason for this lies +in the fact that ``excess'' commissions are being charged for non- +fiduciary purposes. + SEC rule 28(e) encourages turnover and the cost of trading because +mutual fund managers receive revenue from the brokerage firms for +clearing the Funds' securities trades. This explains why the +intelligent approach so widely accepted by the world's most astute +investing minds is thrown out the window in 401(k) plans. Brokerage and +Mutual Fund companies work together to generate excess revenue at the +expense of participants, because they believe they can indiscriminately +do so, not because it is prudent, intelligent, or advisable. + Prior to ERISA, mutual funds used any ``excess'' commission on a +securities transaction to buy additional goods or services from their +chosen brokerage firm. For example, if a trade costs 3.5 cents per +share (trade execution, clearance and settlement), and the brokerage +fixed commission was 5 cents per share, the excess 1.5 cents could +either be used to purchase additional goods or services from the broker +that directly benefited the account holder, or be credited back to +their rightful owners, the account holders. Excess brokerage +commissions (28(e) soft dollars) were handled the same way for IRAs and +qualified plans. + After ERISA, the practice of using such soft dollars in IRAs would +remain the same, but with respect to participants and beneficiaries +within a qualified 401(k) plan subject to rules of fiduciary prudence, +a conflict clearly exists with ERISA sections 403(c)(1), 404(a)(1), +406(a)(1)(D), 406(b)(1) and 406(b)(3). + ERISA 403(c)(1) states that the assets of a plan ``shall +never inure to the benefit of any employer and shall be held for the +exclusive purposes of providing benefits to participants in the plan +and their beneficiaries and defraying reasonable expenses of +administering the plan.'' Significance: Using soft dollars for purposes +other than for the exclusive purpose of providing benefits to +participants and beneficiaries and paying operational costs of the plan +itself is a fiduciary breach. + ERISA 404(a)(1) states that a fiduciary must act prudently +and solely in the interest of the participants and beneficiaries +Significance: Using soft dollars to buy loyalty of brokerage firms, +consultants or other parties-in-interest to the plan is a fiduciary +breach. + ERISA 406(a)(1)(D) states that a fiduciary shall not +transfer to, or use by or for the benefit of a party-in-interest, any +assets of an ERISA governed plan. Significance: Use of soft dollars +could effectively be a transfer to a party-in interest, thereby +creating a fiduciary breach. + Due to the lack of oversight of 28(e) Soft Dollar Revenue in +qualified retirement plans, the Securities and Exchange Commission was +compelled to address the issue before the Congressional Subcommittee on +Capital Markets, Insurance and Government Sponsored Enterprises, +Committee on Financial Services. This occurred on June 18, 2003, +shortly after H.R. 2420, the ``Mutual Funds Integrity and Fee +Transparency Act of 2003'' was presented to the House of +Representatives by Chairman Baker, Ranking Member Kanjorski and other +members of the Subcommittee. According to the testimony of Paul F. +Roye, Director, Division of Investment Management of the SEC, the +Mutual Funds Integrity and Fee Transparency Act would: + Provide investors with disclosures about ``estimated'' +operating expenses incurred by shareholders, soft dollar arrangements, +portfolio transaction costs, sales load break points, directed +brokerage and revenue sharing arrangements. + Provide investors with disclosure of information on how +fund portfolio managers are compensated. + Require fund advisers to submit annual reports to fund +directors on directed brokerage and soft dollar arrangements, as well +as on revenue sharing. + Recognize fiduciary responsibility and obligations of fund +directors to supervise these activities and assure that they are in the +best interest of the fund and its shareholders. + Require the SEC to conduct a study of soft dollar +arrangements to assess conflicts of interest raised by these +arrangements, and examine whether the statutory safe harbor in Section +28(e) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 should be reconsidered or +modified. + While it is commendable that the SEC has decided to act on this +issue, 17 years earlier the U.S. Department of Labor issued ERISA +Technical Release 86-1 notifying the public of this very issue. The +nature of ETR 86-1 was to ``reflect the views of the Pension and +Welfare Benefits Administration (PWBA) with regard to `soft dollar' and +directed commission arrangements pursuant to its responsibility to +administer and enforce the provisions of Title I of the Employee +Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA).'' + An excerpt from ETR 86-1 states: + ``It has come to the attention of PWBA that ERISA fiduciaries may +be involved in several types of `soft-dollar' and directed commission +arrangements which do not qualify for the `safe harbor' provided by +Section 28(e) of the 1934 Act. In some instances, investment managers +direct a portion of a plan's securities trades through specific broker- +dealers, who then apply a percentage of the brokerage commissions to +pay for travel, hotel rooms and other goods and services for such +investment managers which do not qualify as research with the meaning +of Section 28(e). In other instances, plan sponsors who do not exercise +investment discretion with respect to a plan direct the plan's +securities trades to one or more broker-dealers in return for research, +performance evaluation, and other administrative services or discounted +commissions. The Commission (SEC) has indicated that the safe harbor of +Section 28(e) is not available for directed brokerage transactions.'' + Subsequent SEC investigations have shown that illegal ``28(e)'' +revenues have been used by ``non-fiduciary'' consultants to make +certain services available to mutual funds. + Among them: + Conferences and other similar group meetings where the +consultant invites both the ``client'' (i.e. a 401(k) plan sponsor/ +trustees) and representatives of the mutual funds who want to sell +their funds to the client of the consultant. In other words, the mutual +fund pays the consultant a significant amount of money to be invited to +meetings where the consultant's clients will be in attendance. + Sales and marketing support to the mutual fund's staff. + ``Objective looking'' performance reports that paint the +mutual fund in the best light, and facilitate the sale of that fund to +clients of the consultant. + Other ``image enhancement'' or ``sales facilitation'' +services. + Loyalty of consultant or brokerage firm. + 28(e) revenue practices hurt plan participants and their +beneficiaries, and violate ERISA Sections 403(c)(1), 404(a)(1) and +406(a)(1)(D). Illegal 28(e) soft dollars are the most difficult fee to +uncover. +Hidden Costs #3--Sub-Transfer Agent Revenue Sharing + The following is a rather lengthy, but important illustration of +the widespread practice of subsidized record keeping services through +excess mutual fund management fees. + Envision a meeting among three individuals. An employer with 75 +employees, wanting to design a brand new plan for their employees; a +Registered Investment Representative; and a Record Keeper commonly +referred to as a ``Third Party Administrator.'' After the meeting, the +employer requests formal proposals from the Investment Representative +and the Record Keeper. They leave the employer's office and agree to +work together to design a plan that works for all parties. The +Registered Representative and the Record Keeper collaborate and develop +two proposals for the employer to consider. + The first proposal recommends 6 mutual funds, 4 of which are +actively traded mutual funds. As a portion/component of the Funds' +Management Fees, the 4 actively traded mutual funds pay a .5% ``finders +fee'' of each new dollar invested to the Registered Representative plus +a .5% trail commission--referred to as a 12(b)-1 commission. (A more +detailed discussion of 12(b)-1 commission will be forthcoming later in +this testimony). The Record Keeper proposes a $4,000 base fee per year, +plus $60 per participant per year, paid by the employer. + When the employer does the math, he discovers that if each of his +75 employees contributed $100 per semi-monthly pay period, the +Investment Representative would earn $100 x .5% x 75 x 24 = $900 the +first year, and every year thereafter, plus an additional .5% on the +accumulating balance. This $900 doesn't seem like much, especially when +compared to the record keeping fee $8,500 ($4,000 base fee plus $4,500 +(75 participants x $60)). + + SUMMARY OF PROPOSAL A +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Cost item Investment Record keeping +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +Finders Fees...................................................... $900 per year N/A +Ongoing Commissions............................................... $900 and growing N/A +Base Fees......................................................... N/A $4,000 +Per Head Charges.................................................. N/A $4,500 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + The employer looks at the record keeping fees, squirms a little, +and quietly questions whether the record keeper's services are really +worth $8,500 per year. Then he requests Proposal B. Having experienced +that reaction before, the Investment Representative and the Record +Keeper are prepared to present something more palatable. + The second proposal consists of 12 mutual funds, 9 of which are +actively traded. To the employer's delight, proposal B seems much +better. The Investment Representative's compensation remains the same, +but the Record Keeping fee is cut by 70%! The base fee is reduced to +$800 per year, and the per-head charge is reduced to $25. + + SUMMARY OF PROPOSAL B +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Cost item Investment Record keeping +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +Finders Fees...................................................... $900 per year N/A +Ongoing Commissions............................................... $900 and growing N/A +Base Fees......................................................... N/A $800 +Per Head Charges.................................................. N/A $1,875 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + This proposal seemed like the best of both worlds. Twice as many +mutual fund options for one-third the cost! The employer thinks +participants will love it, and of course he loves it, too. It doesn't +occur to the employer that he should question the economics, or whether +there are fiduciary implications to going with one proposal vs. +another. It seems like a no-brainer, so the decision is made to go with +Proposal B. + Fast forward 10 years and the employer now has 150 employees, and +$4 million dollars in the plan. As far as the employer is concerned, +the economics are still the same as the first day the plan was adopted. +However, there was an element the employer didn't understand. Remember +the reaction to the $8,500 fee for record keeping fees? The employer +wasn't certain if that was a fair fee for services rendered. Maybe it +was fair, and if that was the case, the employer might have reduced or +cut-back on various optional ``elements'' of the plan to arrive at a +fee that seemed appropriate, all services considered. + The $2,675 in fees associated with Proposal B seemed about right. +With the growth of the company and the plan, the fact that plan costs +also increased went without saying. Looking back at the original +``deal'', the employer computes the fees and costs as he thinks it +stands today. All things remain the same except for 150 participants +instead of 75, and there are $4 million dollars in assets. + + SUMMARY OF COSTS 10 YEARS LATER--PROPOSAL B + [The ``believed-to-be'' costs] +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Cost item Investment Record keeping +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +Finders Fees...................................................... $1,800 per year N/A +Ongoing Commissions............................................... $20,000 growing N/A +Base Fees......................................................... N/A $800 +Per Head Charges.................................................. N/A $3,750 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + Paying the record keeper for such an extensive array of services +rendered might even be perceived as being a little low. The employer +intuitively knows the record keeper is worth more than $4,550, but is +uncertain ``how much more.'' If the record keeper needed more money, +they would certainly ask for it, and if they don't request more they +must be satisfied. The employer also notices the Investment +Representative is now being paid over $20,000--and given all of the +enrollment and investment education meetings--along with all of the +reports, trustee meetings, and general education given to the +fiduciaries, it might seem ``about right.'' + Luckily for the employer and the participants, the employers' niece +happened to be a student of fiduciary prudence and retirement plan +economics and something seemed ``fishy'' to her. + After looking into the economics of ``Proposal B'' today, the +employer's niece reluctantly brought the bad news. Something has gone +terribly wrong, and the employer is stunned beyond words. Here's how +the true economics look: + + TRUE ECONOMICS +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Cost item Investment Record keeping +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +Finders Fees...................................................... $1,800 per year N/A +Ongoing Commissions............................................... $20,000 growing N/A +Base Fees......................................................... N/A $800 +Per Head Charges.................................................. N/A $30,150 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + How could the record keeper be making more money than the +Investment Representative? Ten thousand dollars more * * * and growing! + Remember the ``collaboration'' the Investment Representative and +Record Keeper originally entered into? Proposal B involved the payment +of Sub-Transfer Agent fees (Revenue Sharing from the Mutual Funds). The +increase in funds was not an added benefit to the employer or employees +as initially believed. Rather, it was a carefully calculated design +element to capture a particular type of revenue sharing based upon two +things: (1) The number of funds offered multiplied by (2) the number of +participants with assets in those funds. + Assume in this case 8 of the 9 actively traded mutual funds are +being utilized by participants. Also assume that the mutual funds each +pay $22 per participant per year. The true economics are therefore 150 +participants x $22 Sub-Transfer Agent Revenue Sharing x 8 Funds = +$26,400. When the existing ``per head'' fee paid by the employer +($3,750) and the base fee ($800) are added to the Revenue Sharing +number, the new total is $26,400 + $3,750 + $800 = $30,950. + The employer is angry for four reasons. First, he feels deceived +because he didn't understand the true economics of the plan. Second, he +feels his ability was impeded to prudently judge whether the services +rendered were worth what the Record Keeper received in actual +compensation. Third, he understands now that the ``extra'' funds had +nothing to do with helping participants build a better portfolio. It +had everything to do with multiplying the potential revenue sharing-- +and that has not helped the participants at all. Fourth, the +realization that the employer has allowed assets to be improperly spent +on services with skewed economics might place him squarely in the cross +hairs of an effective litigator. + Such is the nature of hundreds of thousands of 401(k) and similar +retirement plans across the United States even as you read this. +What is a Sub-Transfer Agent? (and Sub Transfer Agent Revenue Sharing?) + A transfer agent is usually a bank or trust company (or the mutual +fund itself) that executes, clears and settles a security buy or sell +order, and maintains shareholder records (i.e. accounts for ``title'' +of the ownership of the shares). When certain functions of the transfer +agent are sub-contracted to a third party, that third party becomes a +``sub-transfer agent.'' Within the context of this paper, a sub- +transfer agent would be one of the following entities: + 1. A third party administrator. + 2. A bank or trust company performing recordkeeping services. + 3. Some other entity tracking the number of shares held for the +benefit of a specific participant within an individual account plan. + Payment to these parties for this sub-contracted service has come +to be known as ``Sub-Transfer Agent fees.'' Sub-Transfer agent fees +exist solely to support the participant directed account culture in +actively managed mutual funds. + Sub-transfer agent fees are generally paid as a flat dollar, per- +participant, per fund. For example, many funds will pay a third party +administrator $10 per participant, per fund. Other funds will pay a +percentage of assets--such as 5 to 10 basis points. However, some funds +pay up to $22 per participant, per fund or 35 basis points. The +problems with sub- transfer agent fees is not how much is being paid to +the service provider. Rather, the problem is being unaware who is +receiving the payments, and whether or not the payments fairly +represent the value of the service being rendered. The Department of +Labor has made it very clear that a plan sponsor must understand the +value and associated compensation of each individual servicing company, +thereby making the cost of the parts more important than the cost of +the whole. + An estimated 100 million shareholder accounts, or approximately 40 +percent of all mutual funds, are in sub accounts at financial or record +keeping intermediaries at this writing. Approximately $2 billion +dollars per year is paid to third parties for sub-accounting services. +There are potential costly and ERISA-violating problems inherent in +omnibus accounts with underlying participant directed sub-accounts +which are beyond the scope of this testimony. +Hidden Costs #4--Non-Fiduciary Compensation (12(b)-1 commissions) + There are two types of 12(b)-1 fees: + 1. Sales commission 12(b)-1--paid to a registered representative +for selling mutual funds for an individual or within a plan. + 2. Servicing 12(b)-1--paid to a person or entity who services an +account after the sale. + SEC Rule 12(b)-1 was enacted in 1980. It is partially responsible +for the proliferation of mutual funds in individual account plans. +Again, referring to the mutual fund relationship with the distribution +medium (sales force) of the brokerage firm, it creates a conflict of +interest between the brokerage firm and the mutual fund, thereby +rendering each unable to devote their loyalties to the plan +participants. It permits mutual funds to increase their internal fund +expense ratio by up to 1% in aggregate. + The combination of these two commissions may not exceed 1%. For +example, the sales 12(b)-1 could be 50 basis points (.5%) and the +service 12(b)-1 could also be 50 basis points. + It is common to refer to both sales and servicing revenue as +``12(b)-1'' fees, not differentiating between the two. More than half +of all mutual funds have a 12(b)-1 feature. These commissions are +disclosed in the prospectus, but very few plan sponsors understand +their significance to the plan, the participants, and the trustees. + The 12(b)-1 commissions are a concern because non-fiduciary sales +people carefully place products with high 12(b)-1 commissions within +401(k) plans without the full understanding of the plan sponsor or +trustees. Conversely, a Fiduciary Investment Advisor would be obligated +to disclose fees in writing, invoice the plan sponsor or plan for those +stated fees, and credit any 12(b)-1 fees back to the trust. This clear +difference in behavior and reporting shows the crisis that exists in +the industry. Plan sponsors don't know there is a difference; mutual +funds are simply mutual funds to them. + Another seldom considered 12(b)-1 issue is that of unfair subsidy +disparity. Fee subsidy disparity is often referred to by the fiduciary +community as the ``Hidden Tax'' paid by participants with larger than +average account balances because 12(b)-1 commissions pay for non- +fiduciary services. +Illustration + Let's compare two hypothetical plans, Plan ``A'' and Plan ``B.'' +Let's say each has $50 million in assets, both have identical mutual +funds and service providers, each paying 3% (1.50% in trading costs, +and 1.50% in fund management fees). Further, assume that 40% of the +fund management fee pays for revenue sharing arrangements (brokers, +record keepers, insurance agents, and others), and 60% is kept by the +fund manager. Let's also say that Plan ``A'' has 500 employees and Plan +``B'' has 2,500 employees. + Are costs consistent for all employees as a percentage of their +account balances? Yes, of course. But what are the real economics? Take +a look at the following example of a comparison between two +hypothetical plans: + + + +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Fee/Cost element Plan A Plan B +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +Gross fund fees and commissions......................... $1,500,000 ($50,000,000 x $1,500,000 ($50,000,000 x + 3%) 3%) +Revenue sharing......................................... $300,000 (1.50% x 40% x $300,000 (1.50% x 40% x + $50,000,000) $50,000,000) +Revenue Sharing borne by each participant............... $300,000 500 $300,000 2500 + participants = $600 per participants = $120 per + participant participant +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + In this example, the participants of Plan ``A'' are subsidizing the +overhead of Plan ``B.'' +Hidden Costs #5--Variable Annuity Wrap Fees + A Variable Annuity is an investment contract between a plan and an +insurance company where (normally) a series of ongoing deposits are +made to accumulate resources sufficient to pay a future benefit. +Variable Annuities can be sold by insurance agents who have little or +no formal investment or fiduciary training. Variable Annuities are +separate vehicles that invest in mutual funds--they are not mutual +funds in and of themselves. + Variable annuities offer a variety of investment options that are +typically mutual funds investing in stocks, bonds and cash. Gains on +variable annuities are tax deferred whether held in a qualified trust +or not, and there are costs associated with this ``built-in'' tax +deferral. The fee associated with obtaining this tax-deferred benefit +is an insurance component. Therefore, one must ask whether or not +putting a variable annuity in an ERISA-governed vehicle is necessary, +or even wise. In other words, you could buy a lower cost mutual fund +using the inherent benefits of a 401(k) and still get the deferral of +tax. Paying the insurance company for the tax deferral may not be +prudent. Variable annuities generally have higher expenses than +comparable mutual funds, and these fees are assessed in such a way that +each component service is ``wrapped up'' into one aggregate fee. +Accordingly, this aggregate fee is called a ``wrap'' fee. The wrap fee +hides individual component fees and services, which are: + Investment Management: Management fees of the mutual fund +that is contained within the variable annuity. (Note that trading costs +are in addition to the investment management component, and are +extremely difficult to discover in variable annuity contracts.) + Surrender Charges: If withdrawals are made from a variable +annuity within a certain period of time after units are purchased +within the annuity, the insurance company will assess a surrender +charge. The charge is used to reimburse the insurance company for the +commission payments they paid to a broker or insurance agent upfront. +The surrender charge usually starts out higher, and decreases over the +length of the surrender period. + Mortality and Expense risk charge: This charge is equal to +a percentage of the account value, typically 1.25% per year over the +investment management fees--but could be more or less depending on who +is purchasing the annuity. + Administrative Fees: The insurer may deduct charges to +cover record-keeping and other administrative expenses. It is common to +see fees of $25 or $30 per year, or a percentage of each participant's +account value, typically in the range of an additional .15% per year. + Fees and Charges for Other Features: Stepped up death +benefit, a guaranteed minimum income benefit, long-term care insurance +etc. These fees are stated in the annuity contract, and are actuarially +computed based on age, health, etc., and hence differ from participant +to participant. + Bonus Credits: Some insurance companies offer bonus +credits, which is a credit back to the account of percentage of each +purchase--e.g. 3% of each deposit. These types of accounts often have +higher expenses, and the expenses can be larger than the credit. Bonus +credits are generally ``purchased'' with higher surrender charges, +longer surrender periods, higher mortality and expense risk charges. +Hidden Costs #6--Administrative ``Pass Throughs'' + An unfortunate and yet almost universally common in 401(k) plans is +an expense borne by all participants for unnecessary services demanded +by a vocal minority. A fiduciary is obligated to protect and treat all +participants equally. It is a violation of ERISA's exclusive benefit +rule that millions of participants unknowingly pay for the +undisciplined urges of others to immediately wrest benefit from their +retirement plans. Three examples are: + Easy loans taken against a participant's vested balance + Open brokerage options + Investment ``advice'' services + While some may argue that these plan features are available to all +participants equally, we must not confuse matters of coverage and non- +discrimination in benefits rights and features (pursuant to IRC +Sec. 401(a)(4)) with fiduciary prudence. Plan assets should not be used +to pay for services that all Participants do not collectively receive +or benefit from plan assets. In hundreds of thousands of companies +across the U.S. there are assertive individuals, who are the vocal +minority, that want various bells and whistles in their 401(k), and the +unsuspecting end up having to pay for it. This subtle violation of the +exclusive benefit rule is rampant and costly. Plans with optional +benefits that increase the overall cost of plan operation should be +paid for by the individual users or by the plan sponsor, not by the +plan. These amounts vary from plan-to-plan, but they can be +substantial, especially if the fees are ``translated'' into an asset +based charge that goes un-examined year after year. +Hidden Costs #7--Non-Fiduciary Mish-Mash + To wrap up this discussion, it's important to highlight a few +remaining hidden costs. The following is not an all-inclusive list, +because there are dozens of variations to each of these items, and even +a few other costs that are highly complex and difficult to explain. +These are beyond the scope of this hearing, but might be examined as +part of a subsequent hearing. Some of the remaining fees and costs +employers of all sizes are struggling to grasp are: + Share class variances based upon plan size. (i.e. high +load share classes in large plans. Common share classes include A, B, +C, R, etc.) \12\ + Shadow Index Funds. These are basically funds that closely +track passive indexes, but have ``actively managed'' prices. In other +words, they are overly priced index funds, some overpriced by 200% to +300%. + Suspected Inter-Fund pricing discrimination. (Evidence +that this practice is now coming to light, but this is so new that +independent fiduciaries are still trying to grasp the full nature and +extent of this particular issue.) \13\ This is where a mutual fund cuts +``deals'' with preferred investors, and increases fees to non-preferred +clients so that the total fee balances out to what is disclosed in the +prospectus. For example, a prospectus of a two hundred million dollar +fund might state that the fund management fee is 1% of assets. The fund +manager then ``discriminates'' against clients 2--6 by cutting a deal +with preferred Client 1 that reduces their fee by half. + + + +------------------------------------------------------------------------ + Actual + Assets fee +------------------------------------------------------------------------ +Client 1................................... $100,000,000 .50% +Client 2................................... 20,000,000 1.10% +Client 3................................... 20,000,000 1.10% +Client 4................................... 20,000,000 1.10% +Client 5................................... 20,000,000 1.10% +Client 6................................... 20,000,000 1.10% + ---------------------------- + Total................................ $200,000,000 1.00% +------------------------------------------------------------------------ + + Clients 2 through 6 are paying for the backroom ``deal'' between +the fund manager and client 1, and will experience lower returns at the +same time, a clear example of investment return and cost +discrimination. Also, other suspected violations of fiduciary prudence +are coming to light where the ``deal'' isn't with a preferred client, +but with the Investment Representative. This has even more serious +implications when proven to be true. + Expert fiduciaries are still trying to get their arms around this +issue. It's such a startling revelation that independent fiduciaries +don't want to believe it, and hence are trying to find other reasonable +explanations for their findings, hoping it simply isn't so. However, +the economics of 401(k) plans are so defiant, entrenched, and arrogant, +that it might very well be happening more often than one would like to +think. Like Andrew Fastow, the former CFO of the complex ENRON +``special purpose entities,'' maybe the industry thought no one would +ever figure it out. + There is more that can and should be shared with legislators about +other activities in the final markets that adversely affect +participants and beneficiaries. I hope this testimony provides +sufficient background to assist in grasping the issues at hand and +comprehending the necessity of diligently considering possible +solutions. +Possible Solutions + Require full disclosure of all financial service provider +costs and expenses. Create stiff monetary sanctions for any person, +entity, or institution to withhold information from named fiduciaries +for any qualified plan. This would require full transparency of all +service provider activities and costs. It would enable fiduciaries to +better understand the basis for their decisions regarding plan +operations and investments. With improved understanding, the retirement +income security of millions of Americans would be enhanced. + Require fiduciaries to itemize any and all fees and +expenses extracted from plan assets at any level, including trading +commissions, spreads, management fees, soft dollar arrangements, +finders fees, transfer agent fees, and other expenses, and to disclose +those directly to participants on the Summary Annual Report. This will +demonstrate to participants that fiduciaries are aware of the costs the +plan is bearing, and that they are taking responsibility for those +costs. + Hold all individuals or companies who are paid from plan +assets to a fiduciary standard. This includes brokers, insurance +agents, record keepers, actuaries, and others. Those individuals or +professionals unwilling to assume fiduciary responsibility could +negotiate payments directly from plan sponsors. + Require all mutual funds held in a qualified trust (within +the meaning of Internal Revenue Code section 501(a)) to be ``revenue +sharing free'' which would include barring 28(e) soft dollars, 12(b)-1 +marketing or servicing commissions, and sub transfer agent fees. This +would force the industry to price services based upon what +knowledgeable fiduciaries determine to be reasonable and appropriate +and are willing to bear. + Eliminate Department of Labor Regulation 404(c). Plan +sponsors and service providers have hidden behind this regulatory +allowance as a perceived shield from fiduciary liability while ignoring +the plight of workers who desperately need guidance and oversight for +their investments. Rule 404(c) is non-fiduciary at its core, and it +encourages other decisions that are not in the interests of securing +the retirement incomes of American workers. +Conclusion + Thank you for the invitation to testify before this committee. It +is my earnest belief that the workers of America deserve proper +protections for the hard earned savings they have set aside in their +401(k) plans--protections which they are denied in the current state of +the industry. I also believe that the problems with the industry can be +solved rather simply, though it will require confronting powerful +economic interests that support the current system. But America's +workers deserve better than they have received to date from the +providers of financial services. Finally, thank you for beginning the +daunting task of tackling this very important and relevant social issue +that will affect millions in the coming decade. I look forward to +elaborating on this written testimony in more detail during the +question and answer period. + endnotes + \1\ Randy Cloud, founder of CNMLLC. Accredited Investment Fiduciary +Auditor and a member of the Revere Coalition, a non-profit fiduciary +advocacy group of independent investment fiduciaries. + \2\ Stock bonus plans may also have a 401(k) feature. + \3\ Statement by Senate Governmental Affairs Subcommittee on +Financial Management, The Budget, and International Security. November +3, 2003, Senator Peter G. Fitzgerald (R- IL) + \4\ http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract--id=868761 + \5\ http://www.ifa.com/Book/Book--pdf/overview.pdf--``Step 5'' + \6\ Dimensional Fund Advisors, Basic 60/40 Balanced Strategy vs. +Company Plans 1987-2003. FutureMetrics, 2004. + \7\ http://finance.yahoo.com/expert/article/futureinvest/6953-- +``The Truth About Money Management'' + \8\ Ibid--``The Birth of Indexing'' + \9\ http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract--id=868761 page 2 + \10\ ``Fee Forensics, The impact of brokerage expense and trade +execution in mutual fund portfolios.'' 2005 Annual Conference of the +Center for Fiduciary Studies. Santa Fe, New Mexico. + \11\ http://www.efficientfrontier.com/ef/997/tough.htm + \12\ http://www.nasd.com/InvestorInformation/InvestorAlerts/ +MutualFunds/UnderstandingMutualFundClasses/NASDW--006022 + \13\ The following is a startling quote from an actual Independent +Fiduciary fee review: ``We find it noteworthy that the funds in the +Plan are paying out more than half of the revenue they receive for +`investment management'. In fact, one fund (fund name deleted) is +paying out 150% of the revenue that it discloses by prospectus. Several +other funds (mostly name deleted / name deleted funds) pay out more +than 70% of their receipts. Obviously, this indicates that they may be +making up their lost revenues in some other manner. We spot checked the +SAIs of a couple of the Plan's funds and found hidden expenses in +excess of .50% for transaction expenses. Some portion of this money +goes back to the manager in one form or another (research services, +commission rebates, etc.). We estimate that the true investment and +recordkeeping cost of the plan is significantly greater than the .94% +that is revealed by the basic plan expense ratios.'' + ______ + + Chairman Miller. Mr. Chambers? + + STATEMENT OF ROBERT CHAMBERS, ESQ., PARTNER, HELMS, MULLISS & + WICKER, PLLC; CHAIRMAN, AMERICAN BENEFITS COUNCIL + + Mr. Chambers. Good morning, Chairman Miller, Ranking Member +McKeon, members of the committee. My name is Robert Chambers, +and I am a partner in the Charlotte, North Carolina-based, law +firm of Helms, Mulliss & Wicker. As was noted earlier, I am +also the chairman of board of the American Benefits Council, on +whose behalf I am testifying today. + The council very much appreciates the opportunity to +present testimony with respect to 401(k) plan fees. Our goal, +like yours, is that the 401(k) system remains fair and +equitable, that it functions in a transparent manner, and that +it provide meaningful benefits at a fair price. + Our members have been successful in obtaining fee +information and using it to sponsor less expensive and more +efficient 401(k) programs, and yet, at the same time, we think +that there is room for improvement through more universal +disclosure of both fee and other information to both +fiduciaries and to plan participants. + There are three pieces to the fee disclosure puzzle that we +will be discussing today: one, disclosure by service providers +to employers and other fiduciaries; two, disclosure by those +fiduciaries to participants; and, three, disclosure by the +fiduciaries to the government. + Now, this comports with the GAO's recommendations in its +2006 report, as has previously been mentioned, and with the +three-part project that the Department of Labor is currently +pursuing. Admittedly, we have some concerns with some of the +details in the department's proposals, but we absolutely agree +with their general approach. + Now, I would like to take the rest of my time to raise five +points that we think, at the council, bear consideration this +morning. + First, the 401(k) plan system in the United States is +voluntary. It depends on the willingness of employers to offer +plans and the willingness of employees to use them. Whatever +fee disclosure reform efforts evolve, they must not undermine +these basic building blocks. + If a new regiment is overly complicated, overly costly, +some employers will drop their plans. Others will comply and +pass the costs onto participants, either in the form of plan +expenses, or perhaps reduced employer contributions. + Further, and perhaps most important, many employees will be +confused by the overemphasis on fees. Compared to equally +valuable investment consideration, such as diversification, +actual investment performance, and risk factors, and they will +either make unbalanced investment decisions or, even worse, a +decision not to participate at all. + Investment education is based on balance, and neither +Congress, the Department of Labor, nor plan fiduciaries should +counteract that concept through a disproportionate focus on +plan fees. + Second, every new feature that is added to a 401(k) plan +adds new costs. There are mandatory bells and whistles, such as +the benefit statement rules that are new, and permissive bells +and whistles, such as automatic enrollment. But they are all +bells and whistles; they have all been adopted by Congress; and +they all cost money to administer. + Additional fee disclosure will also result in additional +cost. Therefore, we must carefully measure the value of what +may be gained against the cost of the annual disclosure. Let's +make sure that our efforts to reduce costs do not, in the end, +actually reduce savings. + Third, in our system of commerce, it is the quality and +features of a product or service that permit one manufacturer +or service provider to charge more than a competitor. Some cars +cost more than others, as do computers, and, unfortunately, my +plumber. + Similarly, 401(k) plan fees should not be evaluated +independently from the product or service that is provided. +Every participant would be willing to pay higher fees if the +total net return on the investment were increased. Enhanced +disclosure will enable participants to determine whether the +quality of the product or the quality of the provider warrants +it cost. The two are inextricably tied to one another. + Fourth, we acknowledge that fee levels differ among differ +plans, just like cable TV service. Some people want only basic +service; some employers want to provide only a basic 401(k) +plan. But other folks want hundreds of channels, providing, +they expect, an even wider spectrum of entertainment. And many +employers want to provide a similarly broad span of retirement +plan features for their participants. + More bells and whistles, more costs. Enhanced disclosure +will help participants to make decisions among the choices +presented. + It is also true that many smaller employers pay higher +401(k) plan fees. This is usually attributable to fewer lives +over which to amortize fixed costs. We believe that increased +disclosure will exert downward pressure on fee levels in the +marketplace. + Fifth, and finally, some maintain that revenue-sharing is +wrong and should be prohibited. People with this view, we +think, misunderstand how the 401(k) system works. They also +probably think that Toyota manufactures cars. It does not. It +assembles cars. + No one expects Toyota to manufacture all of the glass, all +of the seats, all of the computer components for its vehicles. +They subcontract. And revenue-sharing in the 401(k) context is +simply a way of paying for subcontracting. + One service provider delegates a function to another, who +is able to perform the function more efficiently and at less +cost. Revenue-sharing reduces the overall cost of the plan for +both employers and employees. + So, in conclusion, we are very supportive of enhanced +disclosure of plan fees, but fee disclosure must be addressed +in a way that does not overemphasize fees relative to other +factors in the investment decisionmaking process, nor should it +undermine confidence in the retirement system, or create new +costs that, in turn, could decrease retirement benefits. + I would be happy to answer any questions that you may have. + [The statement of Mr. Chambers follows:] + +Prepared Statement of Robert Chambers, Esq., Partner, Helms, Mulliss & + Wicker, PLLC; Chairman, American Benefits Council + + My name is Robert G. Chambers and I am a partner in the Charlotte, +North Carolina law firm of Helms Mulliss & Wicker. I have advised +clients with respect to 401(k) plan issues since 401(k) was added to +the Internal Revenue Code in 1978. In that regard, my clients have +included both major employers that sponsor 401(k) plans as well as +national financial institutions that provide services to 401(k) plans. + I am also chair of the board of the American Benefits Council +(``Council'') on whose behalf I am testifying today. The Council's +members are primarily major U.S. employers that provide employee +benefits to active and retired workers and that do business in most if +not all states. The Council's membership also includes organizations +that provide services to employers of all sizes regarding their +employee benefit programs. Collectively, the Council's members either +directly sponsor or provide services to retirement and health benefit +plans covering more than 100 million Americans. + The Council very much appreciates the opportunity to present +testimony with respect to 401(k) plan fees. With the decline of the +defined benefit plan system, 401(k) plans have become the primary +retirement plan for millions of Americans. Accordingly, it is more +important than ever for all of us to take appropriate steps to ensure +that 401(k) plans provide those Americans with retirement security. In +that regard, our goal is an effective and fair 401(k) system that +functions in a transparent manner and provides meaningful benefits at a +fair price in terms of fees. +We Support Enhanced Disclosure And Reporting Requirements + With respect to 401(k) plan fees, we believe that this Committee +would be pleased by what our member companies are doing. Our members-- +both plan sponsors and service providers--report to us that plan +fiduciaries are taking extensive steps to ensure that fee levels are +fair and reasonable for their participants. Plan fiduciaries are asking +hard questions regarding the various plan services and fees, and the +fiduciaries are obtaining answers that give them the tools to negotiate +effectively for lower fees and to provide meaningful information to +participants. In the case of small plans with less bargaining power, +plan fiduciaries are using additional fee information to shop more +effectively for service providers. + Are there exceptions to this rosy picture? Of course there are. No +system functions perfectly. So we need to strive to make the system +even better. How can we achieve those improvements? The answer is +conceptually simple: through even more universal disclosure of +meaningful information. We need to ensure that all plan fiduciaries and +service providers follow the practices we are hearing about from our +members. Those practices include disclosure to plan fiduciaries of +direct and indirect fees that service providers receive from the plan +or from unrelated third parties. Those practices also include clear, +meaningful disclosure to participants. + In this regard, we commend the Department of Labor and the +Government Accountability Office (``GAO''). The Department of Labor has +been working on a three-part project to enhance transparency that is +conceptually the same as the enhanced regime we are recommending. This +three-part approach is very similar to the recommendations made by GAO. +One part would require the type of disclosure by service providers to +plan fiduciaries that I refer to above. A second part would require +clear, meaningful disclosure to participants. And a third part would +require plans to report fee information to the Department. We have +concerns regarding certain specific points with respect to the +Department's proposals, but conceptually we are in agreement with the +general approach. We look forward to a constructive dialogue with the +Department as its proposals move forward. + As described in its letter to GAO regarding plan fees, the +Department of Labor has already taken a number of steps to improve +awareness and understanding with respect to plan fees. The Department +makes available on its website important materials designed to help +participants and plan fiduciaries understand plan fees. These materials +include ``A Look at 401(k) Plan Fees for Employees'', which is designed +to assist participants in selecting investment options. For employers +and other plan fiduciaries, the Department makes available +``Understanding Retirement Plan Fees and Expenses'', ``Tips for +Selecting and Monitoring Service Providers for Your Employee Benefit +Plan'', and ``Selecting and Monitoring Pension Consultants--Tips for +Plan Fiduciaries''. In addition, the Department makes available a model +form--called the ``401(k) Plan Fee Disclosure Form''--that is designed +to facilitate the disclosure of plan fees by service providers to plan +fiduciaries and the comparison of these fees. Finally, the Department +has been conducting educational programs across the country that are +designed to educate plan fiduciaries about their duties. + In short, we believe that the Department of Labor and GAO are +making, and have been making, important contributions to improving the +401(k) plan system. In this regard, we are also proud of our own +efforts to improve fee disclosure, which include working in a +constructive manner with the Department to help it improve disclosure +and transparency. For example, recently, a group of associations +submitted to the Department of Labor an extensive list of fee and +expense data elements that plan sponsors can use to discuss fees +effectively with their service providers. (The associations were the +American Benefits Council, the Investment Company Institute, the +American Council of Life Insurers, the American Bankers Association, +and the Securities Industry Association (now the Securities Industry +and Financial Markets Association).) We view disclosure enhancement as +a critical part of our mission to strengthen the 401(k) plan system and +we are committed to continuing to offer our help to this Committee, +other Committees, and the agencies. +Addressing Concerns And Questions + So far, I have been talking about positive things that can be done +to improve the 401(k) plan system. Now I would like to touch on +concerns that I know are shared by this Committee and answer some +questions that have been raised. +We Must Not Undermine The Voluntary System + The success of the 401(k) plan system is dependent on many things, +including very notably the willingness of employers to offer these +plans and the willingness of employees to participate in the plans. It +is critical that any reform efforts not inadvertently undermine these +key building blocks of our system. Clear, meaningful disclosure is +needed; overly complicated and burdensome disclosures would only push +employers and service providers away from the 401(k) plan system. In +particular, burdensome rules would be yet another powerful disincentive +for small employers to maintain plans. Overly complicated disclosure +would also confuse rather than inform participants; participants need +clear meaningful information that is relevant to their decision-making. + In addition, employee confidence is critical to their participation +in the system. If the huge number of employees participating in well- +run efficient 401(k) plans hear only about the 401(k) plan problems and +do not hear about the strengths of the system, their confidence will be +eroded, their participation will decline, and their retirement security +will be undermined. +We Must Not Inadvertently Increase Fees In The Effort To Reduce Them + Every new requirement imposed on the 401(k) plan system has a cost. +And generally it is participants who bear that cost. So it would be +unfortunate and counterproductive if a plethora of new complicated +rules are added in an effort to reduce costs, but the expense of +administering those new rules actually ends up adding to those costs. +The Department of Labor has explicitly raised this exact concern. In +its letter to GAO regarding the GAO plan fee report, the Department +noted that its own fee disclosure project must be designed ``without +imposing undue compliance costs, given that any such costs are likely +to be charged against the individual accounts of participants and +affect their retirement savings.'' + In this regard, it is important to recognize a key point noted in +the GAO report. In the course of numerous plan fee investigations +conducted by the Department of Labor in the late 1990's, no ERISA +violations were found with respect to 401(k) plan fees. Moreover, the +Department of Labor receives enforcement referrals from various +entities, such as federal and state agencies. The GAO report notes that +``only one of the referrals that the [Department of Labor] has closed +over the past 5 years was directly related to fees'' (emphasis added). +In the context of these facts, imposing burdensome new rules and costs +to be borne by participants would be even less justified. +Fees Can Only Be Evaluated In The Context Of The Services They Pay For + Another critical point to bear in mind is that we must not examine +fee amounts out of context. Any specific fee can only be effectively +evaluated in the context of the quality of the service or product that +is being paid for. For example, some actively managed investment +options may logically have higher than average expenses, but it is the +net performance of the option that is critical to retirement plan +sponsors and participants, not the fee component in isolation. We must +avoid studying fees in a vacuum. Fees are very important, but they are +only one component of performance; with respect to investments, other +key components include minimization of risk, diversification, relative +peer group performance, quality of the investment organization, and, of +course, investment return. Our objective should be excellent +performance and service at a fair price. + Another example of this point is that increased fees generally +reflect increased services. In the past several decades, there has been +enormous progress in the development of services and products available +to defined contribution plans (``DC plans'') such as 401(k) plans. For +example, many years ago, plan assets generally were valued once per +quarter--or even once per year--so that employees' accounts were +generally not valued at the current market value. Participants +generally were not permitted to invest their assets in accordance with +their own objectives; the plan fiduciary generally invested all plan +assets together. Today, 401(k) plans generally value plan investments +on a daily basis, and permit participants to make investment exchanges +frequently (often on a daily basis) to achieve their own objectives. +Other new services include, for example, internet access and voice +response systems, on-line distribution and loan modeling, on-line +calculators for comparing deferral options, and investment advice and/ +or education services. + In addition, the legal environment for DC plans used to be simpler, +with far fewer legal requirements and design options. New legal +requirements or options can require significant systems enhancements. +For example, system modifications were needed to address catch-up +contributions, automatic rollovers of distributions between $1,000 and +$5,000, Roth 401(k) options, redemption fees and required holding +periods with respect to plan investment options, employer stock +diversification requirements, default investment notices, automatic +enrollment, and new benefit statement rules. Today, 401(k) plans have +become the dominant retirement vehicle for millions of American +workers. With this change has come the need to help participants +adequately plan for their retirement. Service providers have responded +by developing investment advice offerings, retirement planning and +education, programs to increase employee participation in plans, and +plan distribution options that address a participant's risk of +outliving his or her retirement savings. + Naturally, the new services and products and the needed systems +modifications have a cost. In this regard, we also want to emphasize +that the disclosure rules need to be flexible enough to take into +account the ever evolving 401(k) plan service market. For example, the +rules need to be consistent with the current trend toward reducing the +size of the plan investment menu as well as the trend toward offering a +brokerage account option. + On a related point, we see enhanced plan fee disclosure as another +important step with respect to participant education. And we look +forward to working with this Committee on further participant education +initiatives. +Why Do Fee Levels Differ So Much Among Different Plans? + Different workforces need different services. Accordingly, the +401(k) plan market has attracted a number of different service +providers that have developed numerous service options for plans, often +with different fee structures and different services available for +separate fees. This structure avoids forcing plans to pay for services +that they do not want or use, and increases the options available to +plan sponsors wishing to find providers and services that meet their +and their employees' unique needs. + Concerns have been raised about the higher level of fees for +smaller plans. Many plan fees vary only slightly (if at all) based on +the number of participants in the plan. Accordingly, on a per- +participant basis, plan costs can be much higher for small plans than +for large plans. On a similar point, many costs do not vary with the +size of a participant's account, so plans with small accounts will +often pay much higher fees--on a percentage of assets basis--than plans +with large accounts. These effects are most often a function of the +nature of the services rendered: for example, plans must meet the same +regulatory requirements without regard to whether a plan has 100 +participants or 100,000 participants, and without regard to whether the +average account size is $5,000 or $50,000. +Who Pays DC Plan Fees? + By law, the employer must pay certain fees, such as the cost of +designing a plan. But there are a wide range of fees that are permitted +to be paid by the plan and its participants, such as fees for +investments (which generally constitute the vast majority of a plan's +total fees), recordkeeping, trustee services, participant +communications, investment advice or education, plan loans, compliance +testing, and plan audits. Many employers voluntarily pay for certain +expenses that could be charged to the plan and its participants, such +as recordkeeping, administrative, auditing, and certain legal expenses. +On the other hand, investment expenses, such as expenses of a +particular mutual fund or other investment option, are generally borne +by the participant whose account is invested in the fund. +Why Does One Service Provider Sometimes Receive Fees From Another + Service Provider? Is This ``Revenue Sharing''? Is This A + Problem Area? + Some maintain that ``revenue sharing'' is wrong and should be +prohibited. That view reflects a misunderstanding of how the 401(k) +plan system works. Let me explain. + It is not uncommon, for example, for mutual funds or other +investment options to pay other plan service providers for services +needed by the funds. For example, assume that participants of a plan +invest some of their assets in Mutual Fund A. If these were retail +investors in Mutual Fund A, Fund A would need to: maintain separate +accounts for each investor; provide a means for investors to interact +with Fund A (e.g., internet access, voice response systems, telephone +service representatives); make certain that investors receive +statements, investment confirmations, and any statutory notices; and +prepare the appropriate tax reporting for any distributions. When a +participant invests in Fund A through a retirement plan, the plan's +recordkeeper generally assumes these responsibilities and bears the +cost of performing them. It is not uncommon for Fund A to pay the +plan's recordkeeper for performing the services that the fund would +otherwise have to perform in the retail environment. + Such ``inter-service provider'' fees arise because different +service providers cooperate in providing a total service package to a +plan. ``Revenue sharing'' is the term often used to described these +types of inter-service provider fees. In fact, fund companies typically +designate a portion of their overall expense ratio as ``shareholder +servicing fees'', and it is this expense stream that is typically used +to pay other providers. + There is nothing inherently problematic regarding inter-service +provider fees and the current-law prohibited transaction rules preclude +inter-service provider arrangements that would create conflicts of +interest. For example, assume that a plan pays Mutual Fund A $100 for +investment services and the plan pays unrelated Service Provider B $50 +for recordkeeping services. Assume further that Mutual Fund A pays +Service Provider B $10 to provide shareholder services so that A +receives $90 net and B receives a total of $60. Assume further that B +discloses the receipt of the extra $10 to the plan fiduciary so that +the plan fiduciary can evaluate the fee and the relationship between +Mutual Fund A and Service Provider B. If $100 is a fair price for +investment services, why does it matter whether A performs shareholder +servicing itself or subcontracts with Service Provider B to perform +those services? In other words, if Mutual Fund A performed the services +itself, the cost to the plan would be the same $150, but A would keep +the full $100, instead of paying $10 of its $100 fee to B. And if $50 +is a fair price for recordkeeping services provided to the plan, why +does it matter if B receives an additional $10 for services rendered to +A? This example illustrates how an efficient subcontracting +relationship works among service providers. + We are not suggesting that disclosure of the inter-service provider +fees is not important. On the contrary, as discussed previously, we are +very supportive of such disclosure. But the existence of these +arrangements is not indicative of an inherent problem or a sign that +401(k) participants are paying excessive fees. If fully disclosed, +these subcontracting arrangements can, on the contrary, be quite +efficient and the current-law prohibited transaction rules are already +in place to preclude conflicts of interest. +Are Plan Fees Too High? + Competition among investment options and service providers is +intense, which exerts downward pressure on fee levels. For example, as +noted above, investment expenses are generally the largest plan +expense. These expenses are reviewed in the context of reviewing the +performance of investment options. Plans routinely review such +performance: a 2006 survey by the Profit Sharing/401(k) Council of +America indicates that 62% of plans review plan investments at least +quarterly and substantially all plans conduct such a review at least +annually. + In fact, plan investment fees are much lower than fees outside the +context of plans. For example, a 2006 study by the Investment Company +Institute found that in 2005 the average asset-weighted expense ratio +for 401(k) plans investing in stock mutual funds was .76%, compared to +a .91% average for all stock mutual funds. +Conclusion + We are very supportive of enhanced disclosure of plan fees. But fee +disclosure must be addressed in a way that does not undermine +participant confidence in the retirement system and does not create new +costs that have the counterproductive effect of increasing fees borne +by participants. We are committed to working with the government to +make improvements in the fee disclosure area, including reporting to +the Department of Labor. We believe that the best approach to the fee +issue is through simple, clear disclosures that enable plan sponsors +and participants to understand and compare fees in the context of the +services and benefits being offered under the plan. + ______ + + Chairman Miller. Thank you. + Mr. Butler? + +STATEMENT OF STEPHEN J. BUTLER, PRESIDENT AND FOUNDER, PENSION + DYNAMICS CORP. + + Mr. Butler. Chairman Miller, Congressman McKeon and members +of the committee, my name is Steve Butler. I am the founder and +president of the Pension Administration Firm in Pleasant Hill, +California. + My company is one of the largest independent administration +firms in Northern California, and we have operated well over a +thousand retirement plans over the past 30 years. + I have written two books on the subject. The first was +``The Decisionmaker's Guide to 401(k) Plans.'' The second was +entitled ``401(k) Today.'' Both books identified hidden costs +and offered a formula for making an effective comparison +between the total costs of different vendors and vendor +combinations. + This led to some national publicity focused on what we +called the Butler Index. This is an index of total costs, +employee and employer, on a same plan, which was then the +subject of a New York Times article. The article compared about +a dozen major vendors in the 401(k) industry, and the results +were shocking. Money magazine then wrote a feature article +based on the Butler Index. + A persistent lack of disclosure leads many plan +decisionmakers to purchase 401(k) plans that careful analysis +of costs would show to be a poor value for participants. + A number of academic and industry studies show that just an +extra 1 percent of assets charged to a plan will reduce +retirement account balances by roughly 20 percent over a 30- +year period. This means that someone retiring will have 80 +percent of what they otherwise would have had, if fees had been +reasonable and competitive. + The need for full disclosure of 401(k) fees should be as +obvious as the reasons for any consumer protection laws. +Throughout the history of these plans, a subset of the +financial services industry has advertised free 401(k) bundle +services to sponsoring employers, while the actual costs were +billed to plan participants. And if costs were disclosed at +all, a breakdown of these costs has not been offered to those +participants. + In many cases, they were not disclosed to or fully +understood by the company decisionmakers. To date, the +Department of Labor has still not required bundled 401(k) +vendors to fully disclose all the real fees associated with +these plans. + Today, American workers have what I estimate to be $3 +trillion in 401(k) plans. To pay for the record-keeping and +money management services, they are paying somewhere between 1 +percent and 2 percent, $30 billion to $60 billion a year. And, +of course, that will only increase. + Charges for these basic functions can differ by as much as +600 percent for essentially the same range of services from +different providers. This says that, while some plan +participants are receiving good value, others are being grossly +overcharged. + By comparison in the automobile industry, there is the +manufacturer suggested retail price, commonly known as the +sticker price, a legal requirement that the price be emblazoned +on the window of every car sold in this country, with the +component costs of each option listed separately. + There is nothing that should stand in the way of an +equivalent, simple, and elegant solution to a problem that is +otherwise costing American retirement savers as much as 20 +percent of their ultimate retirement nest egg. + The approach of the Butler Index was to identify and +breakdown all costs of either a bundled plan or combination of +vendors. It was not rocket science. Anyone smart enough to +operate a 401(k) plan today is smart enough to be able to go +one step further, to identify and disclose the fees it is +charging and what those fees are for. + Anyone asking for an exemption from these disclosure +requirements because they say it can't be done is insulting our +intelligence. Are they really trying to say that they have no +way of determining the extent to which they are making a profit +on a 401(k) plan client? + Any 401(k) is better than no 401(k), even if it an +expensive one. However, company owners and managers owe it to +themselves and their employees to make informed decisions about +the plans they purchase on behalf of their fellow employees. In +fact, the failure of corporate plan sponsors to have adequate +disclosure of 401(k) fees and a breakdown of what those fees +are for has been the subject of recent class-action lawsuits +brought by participants, alleging that the plan sponsors +breached their fiduciary duties under ERISA. + Full disclosure of 401(k) plan fees to corporate plan +sponsors and participants will allow for cost comparisons. Give +the number of players in the 401(k) marketplace, this will +create competition, ultimately leading to reduced costs, to the +benefit of participants. + In the absence of full disclosure, we see the equivalent of +the fog of war. The battle for extremely valuable retirement +plan money is so intense that the industry cannot resist any +steps that enhance the perceived value of their product. The +simplest of these enhancements has been to bury the total cost +and fees charged to participants and then fail to disclose +them. + As I see it, this is the problem that needs to be addressed +with disclosure legislation and/or appropriately crafted +Department of Labor regulations. + Thank you. + [The statement of Mr. Butler follows:] + + Prepared Statement of Stephen J. Butler, President and Founder, + Pension Dynamics Corp. + +A Brief History + The 401(k) phenomenon is an accident in legislative history that +has changed the face of America's retirement system. Voluntary pre-tax +contributions from employees have generated substantial financial +resources that provide a comfortable retirement for many. Considering +the average American employee, early projections indicated that these +plans would generate roughly five times the asset value at retirement +than would have been received from the continuation of what was then a +combination of qualified profit sharing, money purchase and defined +benefit plans. Current statistics for the average employee who has been +a participant for at least twenty years (and who is in their early +60's) support this original projection. The $3 trillion now accumulated +in 401(k) plans offers a testimonial to their success. + The fact that pension laws have evolved to provide what amount to +``portable'' pension plans is critical in a country where the average +employee changes jobs every seven years. The Bureau of Labor Statistics +recently determined that the average employee born between 1957 and +1964 has had 10.5 different jobs between ages 18 and 40. Twenty-one +percent of this group have had 15 jobs. Only fifteen percent have had +fewer than four jobs. Those with college degrees had no better +statistics regarding job stability than those without degrees. + To the extent that the traditional retirement plan system (that +which preceded the 401(k) era) failed to meet expectations, its failure +was largely attributable to the practical reality of employee turnover. +Traditional pension benefits were designed to create a form of ``golden +handcuffs'' with vesting schedules that rewarded only those employees +who remained with a company long enough to become vested in their +retirement benefits. In the early '70's, this could have required as +much as ten years of service. A direct quote from President Reagan at +the time was that he wanted to create ``portable pension programs.'' +Over 70% of working Americans work for companies having less than 100 +employees. A large percentage of these employees work for companies +with less than 25 employees. In the past, small, relatively unstable +companies rarely offered traditional retirement plans when employer +contributions were the only source of funds. Today, many offer some +variation of a 401(k) plan or the small-company equivalent in the form +of SIMPLE 401(k)'s. + The complicated laws requiring 401(k) plans to pass non- +discrimination tests has compelled company owners and highly- +compensated managers to spend time and money promoting plans to all +rank and file employees. Without substantial contribution percentages +from these non-highly compensated people, the managers were limited to +contribution amounts below the legal maximums. This has prompted +management to do everything in their power to promote the plans. +Matching contributions, company discretionary contributions, employee +meetings, individual financial advice and careful selection of +investments are all a part of this promotional effort leading to the +success of these plans. +Cost to Participants in General + The costs to 401(k) participants struggling to save for retirement +is a detriment that has marred what would otherwise have been the +unqualified success of the 401(k) phenomenon. Excessive fees, just over +the past twenty years, have reduced participant account balances by an +average of 15%. On a projected basis, excessive fees charged to +participants will have reduced retirement ``nest-eggs'' by 20% +according to a wide variety of organizations conducting research on the +subject. +Understanding the Fundamentals of 401(k) Costs + Fees taken from plan assets to pay for administration and/or money +management are paid with funds that could otherwise be earning and +compounding on a tax-deferred basis. The ``Magic of Compound Interest'' +works against employees to dramatically magnify the loss of these +missing dollars. The business term for this condition is ``opportunity +cost''--the calculated cost in dollars of a lost opportunity. + Example: + The best illustration of the cost of excessive fees is to project a +flow of 401(k) contributions over time at percentage returns that +reflect the difference of 1% (a typical amount of an ``excessive +fee.'') Choosing $10,000 as an employee contribution amount is +reasonable considering that we are looking well into the future. The +median income today is $71,000 and the average contribution amount is +6-7%. In many cases, both members of a married couple are contributing, +so $10,000 per year is not unreasonable. The returns for the American +stock market have averaged 10% per year over a long historical period. + + THE OPPORTUNITY COST OF A 1% EXCESS COST--$10,000 ANNUAL CONTRIBUTION +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Account value Account value Account value + Percentage annual return 10 years 20 years 30 years +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +10%............................................................. 171,178 641,491 1,925,836 +9%.............................................................. 162,568 566,549 1,570,441 +Cost of 1% fee.................................................. 8,610 74,942 355,395 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + For the 20-year period through the 1980's and 1990's, the stock +market averaged a 16% rate of return. Looking at what might be higher +underlying rates of return going forward, the opportunity cost of the +missing 1% is much higher. By 2000, many employees in expensive plans +who had been participating for twenty years effectively paid the +following amounts in opportunity costs as a result of high fees during +that 20-year period. + + THE OPPORTUNITY COST OF A 1% EXCESS COST--$10,000 ANNUAL CONTRIBUTION +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + Account value Account value Account value + Percentage annual return 10 years 20 years 30 years +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- +15%............................................................. 232,057 1,279,641 6,008,782 +14%............................................................. 215,656 1,079,734 4,541,874 +Cost of 1% fee.................................................. 16,401 199,907 1,466,908 +---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- + + After twenty years, this illustrates the actual cost for what might +have been a single employee contributing $10,000 a year (or two people +contributing $5,000 each) in the twenty years ending in 2000. Multiply +these single-participant detrimental effects times the $3 trillion now +in 401(k) plans and we can understand why the fee issue is critical. + Stop and recall for a moment the ``Rule of 72'' which states that +money earning 7.2% doubles every ten years, and money earning 10% +doubles every 7.2 years. Today's $3 trillion can be reasonably expected +to double twice to $12 trillion in the next 14 years, thanks to +reasonable investment returns and annual contributions. Excessive, +undisclosed fees scheduled to cost participants as much as $2 trillion +dollars is the problem we are here to try to correct. +Where the Abuse Begins + The greatest abuses are seen in the small-company environment where +the average company owner is not a mutual fund or retirement plan +expert. Large companies, by comparison, have reasonably sophisticated +decision-makers. Xerox, for example, operated its own mutual funds and +charged participants just 3/100ths of one percent per year. +Participants in many small-company plans can be paying as much as 3 +full percentage points--exactly 100 times more for the same level of +services. + Technically, all fees charged to participants are disclosed today +to plan sponsor decision-makers, but not all fees are disclosed to +participants. In the insurance industry, for example, the practice of +non-disclosure was justified by the rationale that ``fees didn't +matter--net investment results were all that participants needed to +see.'' This was an actual quote from the marketing Vice President of a +major insurance company when interviewed by MONEY magazine in 1998. + Fees charged to participants may be stated in the investment +materials, but they remain effectively hidden on an ongoing basis +because participants never receive a bill and never see a separate line +item outlining what their costs, in dollars, have been. + According to FORBES magazine, the mutual fund industry is the +world's most profitable as it earns a consistent 30% pre-tax profit. +Investors are not fee sensitive because they are focused on returns. +Generally this means ``chasing last year's best performing mutual +funds.'' + In today's seamless electronic financial services arena, the hard- +dollar cost of administering a mutual fund with at least $50,000 is 6/ +100ths of one percent per year--approximately $30. Virtually all 401(k) +plans are administered in pooled accounts where the investor is the +plan itself--not the individual employee. As a result, virtually all +401(k) accounts, on a fund-by-fund basis, meet this $50,000 benchmark, +meaning that the profit on the account is anything beyond the 6/100ths +being charged. If the average mutual fund charge in a 401(k) investment +is 1 full percentage point per year, the profit on those accounts might +be as high as 94%. + In all discussions regarding fees, we have to take as a given that +no single mutual fund or fund family can show that that they have +consistently earned a higher rate of return (to justify higher fees) +for any sustained length of time. The money management industry is a +``zero sum game'' in which all players revert to the norm at some +point. Moreover, even when we can review past performance, there is no +way to know prospectively whose performance might compensate for an +excessive fee going forward. Over longer periods of time, a difference +in performance among funds of the same type can be largely attributed +to the difference in their costs to investors. +How 401(k) Plans are Structured + Most 401(k) money is maintained today in a ``daily-valued'' +electronic environment managed by the mutual fund or insurance +companies themselves or the transfer agent industry that services the +mutual fund industry. Plan participants can dial up their account +information on an 800 voice-response number, but by far the most +popular access is through the Internet. The raw cost of providing this +seamless, electronic recordkeeping function is approximately $50 per +year per participant. This is referred to as the ``recordkeeping fee.'' +It is the cost of maintaining the accounting of the participant's +account. + Apart from the money management, there is the cost of complying +with the layers of retirement plan regulations dictated by ERISA. This +work is concentrated immediately after the end of every year when the +discrimination testing must be completed. Later in the year, the +government reporting form (Form 5500) for the plan must be completed +and submitted. It is essentially a balance sheet and income statement +for the plan. The cost of this compliance testing and administration is +typically about $35-$60 per participant with a base company fee of +$1,000- $1,500. +An Illustration of Fees in a Typical Plan + We can use an example a plan with 50 participants and $3,000,000 in +assets. This is typical of an engineering or professional firm that has +had a plan for twenty years. + The record keeping and compliance cost for these 50 employees +should be roughly $130 per employee. If the true cost of money +management is only 6/100ths of a percent, the money management cost for +$3,000,000 would be $1,800. The total cost of the plan would be $7,800. +By comparison, a typical vendor in the industry today would be charging +an average of $36,500 for this plan. Some have scheduled fees that +would amount to as much as $60,000 or 2% of assets. + While a plan sponsor (the company) might be happy to pay for the +administration cost, it will never pay total fees of this magnitude. +Asset-based money management fees will always be charged to +participants where they will be largely ignored. After all, no +participant ever receives a bill or writes a check for these costs. +They are automatically deducted from what would have been earnings--or +from principal in years when earnings may be negative. +Techniques that Obscure the Magnitude of Fees + Having established that hidden excessive costs are a guaranteed +detriment to optimizing savings results over time, it is generally easy +to identify them when we know where to look. Some of the more difficult +hidden costs, however, are those that are buried in the process and +that will never show up in any stated cost to participants. +Non-disclosure at Participant Level in ``Bundled Plans'' + In the 401(k) marketplace, participants are told the annual expense +ratios of the mutual funds offered by the plan, but administrative fees +charged to their accounts are typically disclosed only in an annuity +contract signed by the plan sponsor. This percentage amount is referred +to as the ``wrap fee'' and it is typically one or two percent in a +small company environment. The insurance industry is not legislated by +federal laws, so the normal disclosure requirements demanded of the +fund industry do not apply to insurance companies legislated only by +state governments. In the mutual fund industry, the cost of +administration, if presented as being ``free,'' is usually imbedded in +the expense ratios of the funds. Comparable funds, if not priced to +support administration, could generally be found that would be less +expensive for participants. + These plans that combine investment products with administration +all provided by one company are referred to as ``bundled'' plans, and +the providers of such plans are suggesting that ``bundled'' plans be +exempt from any disclosure requirement to come out of these hearings. +With what I estimate to be 70% of all 401(k) plans provided in this +``bundled'' format, making them exempt would emasculate any new +disclosure requirements. +Mutual Fund Industry--Proprietary Fund Requirement + In the mutual fund industry, the fees to participants are disclosed +because they are the normal annual expense ratios of the funds. They +are spelled out in the prospectus of each fund and today are +universally summarized in the employee promotional literature. The +mutual fund industry does not add a wrap fee. Instead, a company such +as Fidelity will insist that at least half of the funds selected for +the plan include their own proprietary funds. Remembering that the +profit from a 401(k) account can be as much as 94% to the fund family, +the insistence that at least half of the funds come from the fund +family's proprietary list ensures that the plan will be profitable. A +refinement of this technique is to require that the so-called ``core +funds'' will be proprietary. These are the large-company or balanced +funds that traditionally attract as much as 70% of the money in the +plan. So, while the fund requirement based on the number of funds may +only be half of the offerings, the percentage of employee money in +those funds can easily be 70% or more. + The balance of the funds offered in the plan may come from other +fund companies as part of an effort to create a ``veneer of +objectivity'' for marketing reasons. These other fund families will +typically be limited to just those funds that charge enough to pay the +primary fund family 25/100ths of one percent and possibly some +additional funds to buy ``shelf space'' on the ``platform'' offered by +the primary fund family selling and administering the plan. + What does this practice cost the participant? No single fund family +offers superior funds across the entire spectrum of the industry. +Common sense would tell us that selecting from a vast universe of +choices will generate better fund selection than a limited universe +from just a single fund family. Here, we are selecting funds for the +convenience and pricing demands of the vendor--not with the sole +purpose of improving the outcome for the participant. Knowing that this +is the case explains why major mutual fund companies in the 401(k) +industry refuse to be construed as fiduciaries of the plan. Selling +their own funds would be a prohibited transaction and would violate the +requirement that fiduciaries make decisions based upon the ``sole +interests of participants.'' + In the sample plan above, (50 employees and $3,000,000) most +vendors today would offer to do the administration and record keeping +at no cost to the plan sponsor. A quick review of the arithmetic would +explain why. Those administrative costs would have been about $7,000 +and the plan is charging participants $30,000. +Barring the Exit--Back-end Charges for Plan Sponsors who Want to Leave + The most egregious examples of excessive fees today are found in +plans that are using share classes or annuity products that pay +commissions up front and then have high ongoing fees to participants to +offset, over time, the commission that was paid up-front. If a plan +sponsor chooses to leave one of these plans there will be a +``contingent deferred sales charge'' otherwise known as a ``back-end +load.'' Eventually, the load grades down and disappears after five to +seven years, but in the meantime, the plan sponsor can not leave +without subjecting participants to an exit charge that can be as high +as 5% of their assets. Moreover, the law specifically bars a plan +sponsor from paying that cost as a company expense, because plan +contributions can only be made as a percent of compensation--never as a +percent of assets. These are the plans that can be charging +participants as much as 3% per year. Once introduced, they are locked +in by exit charges for at least five years. + The insurance industry and the subset of the mutual fund industry +selling through the NASD brokerage industry are selling these 401(k) +packages with back-end loads. The pure no-load sub-set of the fund +industry does not offer this format. The back-end-load phenomenon +occurs only in an environment where a mutual fund sales person or +insurance agent requires a sales commission that has to be charged to +the plan. +Funds as a ``Feeding Trough'' for the Brokerage Industry + As yet another example of a hidden fee, FORBES magazine published +an article entitled, `` What's the Matter With Brokers' Funds?'' The +fact that these funds generate relatively poor performance is well- +established, and the reasons have to do with two facts. The article +stated that ``* * * the whole psyche of a brokerage firm is built +around selling, not buying * * * Analysts at wire houses get ahead by +helping underwriters, not by being skeptical.'' This is essentially +saying that the brokerage-sponsored funds are used as a resource for +investing in the kind of companies that the firm was underwriting. High +turnover of assets in the funds also generated trading fees for the +brokerage firm. I was once told by a Prudential-Bache retirement plan +representative offering a ``free'' plan to a plan sponsor that ``once +we have the assets, we don't have to worry about making money.'' The +FORBES article went on to say, ``Another problem is that broker- +sponsored funds tend to have steep expense ratios.'' +How an Expensive Plan Can Be Marketed + Thanks to the benefit of hindsight, a classic marketing ploy +involves a presentation of funds from a new vendor candidate that have +substantially out-performed the incumbent selection of the existing +vendor. The current vendor, of course, is saddled with a selection of +funds that were chosen three years previously in most cases. There are +the problems of logistics and inertia that stand in the way of making +changes in plans unless performance has fallen off a cliff. Of course, +in this environment, a new set of fund choices will always look +substantially better. The average plan sponsor rarely thinks to ask for +examples of what the proposed new vendor's investment selections might +be for a plan that they have operated for three years. There would +typically be no improvement shown by this comparison. + This is symptomatic of how the consultants and marketing personnel +in the industry can appear to be offering improvement when, in fact, +they are simply rearranging the deck chairs and adding to the level of +hidden fees in many cases. Representations of superior performance are +a major tool used to take the focus away from participant fees. +Misinformed Decision-making on the part of Plan Sponsors + Section 404(c) is a U.S. Department of Labor regulation +establishing requirements for plan sponsors that reduces their +liability for making poor decisions with regard to the plan. Employees +must be able to change investments and receive statements at least +quarterly. They must be offered three basic fund types including a +money market or guaranteed fixed income option. Finally, the plan must +have a written investment policy statement, and employees should be +provided with investment education (the latter being undefined and +unspecified.) + Ironically, Section 404( c ) proved to be a solution looking for a +problem which then created a far more serious disadvantage for the +employee participant. Since 1980 or the earliest days of the 401(k) +phenomenon, virtually all plans offered quarterly statements and +investment changes and a selection of different investment types. +Remember that senior executives were major beneficiaries of these plans +and they were inclined to want investment quality and flexibility. +Virtually all plans operated under what was essentially an investment +policy statement because decision-makers wanted decent investment +choices for themselves. + The financial services community seized on Section 404( c ) as the +reason for hiring them to monitor the plan and therefore reduce +liability. In fact, there was no practical liability for reasons having +to do with 404( c ). At industry conferences, lawyers were quick to +point out that there were no lawsuits anywhere in the country brought +by employees or groups of employees offered a selection of name-brand +mutual funds and a rudimentary investment education and plan +promotional effort. + The law of unintended consequences quickly created a ``create the +need'' opportunity for the financial services community. An army of +qualified and experienced ``advisors'' fanned out across the 401(k) +Plan Sponsor community and talked about the potential liability of not +using professional help and advice with regard to operating the plan. +What this universe of advisors did not point out was that a.) there was +no practical legal problem stemming from the way plans were typically +being operated, and b.) the cost of this advisory service was going to +be, at a minimum, one half percent to one full percentage point charged +to plan participants--a cost that guaranteed a loss of up to 20% of +retirement assets for each participant. + Meanwhile, there have been some lawsuits successfully filed against +plan sponsors. The first that I am aware of was against First Union +Bank settled for $25 million in behalf of the bank's employees. The +bank was operating a collection of mutual funds, (Evergreen Funds which +they owned at the time) and these funds were charging bank employees +substantially more than 401(k) investments the bank was selling to its +bank customers. + In the same vein, the recent class action suits against Fortune 500 +companies such as Caterpillar, Boeing, Kraft and International Paper +are all centered on fees--not a lack of reporting, investment choice or +investment education. +Avoiding Compliance Responsibility + While the financial services industry has seized upon Section 404 ( +c ) and the scare tactics it can foster, they have deliberately avoided +responsibility for most of the other IRS and Labor Department +Regulations that they should be upholding when representing themselves +as providing 401(k) administrative services. A typical service contract +will have hold harmless language such as ``the design and ongoing +operation of your retirement plan needs to be reviewed by your tax and +legal advisors.'' The ``bundled provider'' contract of one of the +nation's largest mutual fund companies says the company will perform +the 401(k) test and coverage test, but all other tests are the +responsibility of the plan sponsor. In effect, the financial services +industry is saying that they will do the work, but they are not +offering a guarantee that it will be done correctly or completely. A +plan failing an audit can cost the plan sponsor a substantial amount of +money in legal fees and corrective measures. In an indirect way, this +misrepresentation could be construed to be a hidden fee. The average +plan sponsor assumes that the major financial institution handling +their plan has taken responsibility for its compliance with all +government regulations. In my experience, however, the immediate +response when compliance problems arise is the voice on the phone +saying, ``read your contract.'' +The Search for a Solution + To identify a solution, a process would involve working back from a +perfect, if admittedly impractical, model. + Ideally, the best 401(k) plan would be one that charged nothing to +the plan. All fees, even those associated with managing the mutual +fund, would be charged to the company and paid with tax-deductible +corporate dollars. A typical employee would be better off electing to +have his or her taxable salary reduced slightly to help defray all or a +portion of these costs. This would be far better than having the same +costs deducted from plan assets that could be compounding on a tax- +deferred basis. + Here's an actual example of that positive arithmetic. Over 800 +dentists use a money management firm to manage retirement assets at +their respective practices. The firm charges 1% of assets and routinely +levies this charge against plan assets. In one actual case, I pointed +out to a dentist that the firm was free to bill his practice for what, +in this case was $15,000 per year on $1.5 million of assets. The net +cost to the dentist billed directly, considering his 50% marginal state +and federal tax bracket was $7,500. Instead, the dentist was paying +that year's $15,000 with money in his plan that in 7.2 years (at a 10% +annual return) would have doubled to $30,000. In 14.4 years, it would +have doubled again to $60,000--in 22 years, $120,000 etc. Obviously, +the dentist asked to be billed directly and then started wondering if +1% might be little high for mediocre investment management that failed +to beat basic benchmarks. The financial services industry will always +opt to bill the plan directly because they do not want fees to become +an issue. The arrangement outlined above had persisted for over twenty +years. The billing format had a projected cost for the dentist and his +employees of well over one million dollars of opportunity cost--a cost +that was reduced to a fraction of that amount in future years with the +stroke of a pen. + Xerox charged just 3/100ths of one percent to its employees. +Vanguard, on large amounts of money, can charge as little as 6/100ths +of a percent and still make a profit. DFA is yet another mutual fund +company renowned for its Vanguard-equivalent low fees. These +organizations offer mute testimony to the fact that it doesn't have to +cost what most of the industry charges to invest pools of money. An +oligopolistic situation exists thanks to buyers who are unaware of the +impact of fees. With few exceptions, nobody in the financial services +industry wants to see this condition change. +The Solution + A simple but impractical solution would be to bar any organization +that manages money from actually selling and administering 401(k) +plans. The industry selling plans would be barred from receiving any +revenue-sharing from the money management (mutual fund) industry. This +would end the hidden fee elements seen in the brokerage industry and +mutual fund industry where the sale of 401(k) plans is an engine for +selling proprietary funds and generating trading commissions. There are +3,500 third party administrators across the country today who are +independent of major financial institutions and that perform +recordkeeping services and compliance work for retirement plans. Some +of these companies, such as Hewitt Associates and Milliman and Roberts, +are substantial and equipped to handle the nation's largest plans. +Without this separation between product producers and 401(k) +administration and sales, it is difficult to see how some of the more +subtle examples of hidden costs can be avoided. Considering the +foothold that mutual fund companies have in the industry, however, it +is difficult to envision this as a practical solution. The horse is out +of the barn. + The next option would be to have a national standard fee disclosure +form required of any 401(k) presentation and require that it be renewed +to reflect any change in investment mix. This standard would require +that the cost in dollars and compound earnings over ten and twenty year +time periods would be based upon the average fee charged to +participants, assuming an even mix of investments across the entire +spectrum of fund offerings. This would be stated on the front page of +the 401(k) presentation and as part of the Summary Plan Description. In +other words, a 401(k) vendor would have to show what the average +opportunity cost would amount to over ten and twenty years based upon +the average fee charged to a $10,000 per year contribution. It would be +reasonable to assume a 10% rate of return as the starting point or +gross return on investments assuming no fee. Fees would then be +subtracted from this percentage amount, and the compound results would +be illustrated. Using an average contribution of $10,000 per year would +be simple (and inspirational.) + This comparison would illustrate the dramatic difference in costs +over time between different vendors. It would offer a reality check for +the average decision-maker who might otherwise have chosen a hidden- +cost but expensive plan for his or her company. It is critical to +require that the comparison use an example in dollars as I have +suggested. To just require a stated percentage cost is too abstract. +Even investment professionals have a hard time grasping the magnitude +of opportunity cost presented by just a fraction of a percent in excess +costs. +The Outcome and Benefit to Those Saving for Retirement + Saving fees increases retirement benefits, in the aggregate, by as +much as 15%-20%. How can this not be important enough to enact +disclosure standards demanded of every company in the industry? +Decision-makers may still purchase expensive plans for their employees, +but not without hearing from the ``self-styled mutual fund experts'' +that manage to find a voice in every company. An army of retirement +savers have now deposited $3 trillion in their 401(k) plans. They are +rapidly becoming a nation of reasonably sophisticated investors. For +the most part, they know how to diversify investments, and they have +lived through the volatility of stock market performance. This is a +clear case where the glass is half full. The financial services +industry can be commended for getting us this far. Going forward, +however, we can improve results by insisting on an educational tool +(comprehensive cost disclosure) that the industry acting on its own is +inclined to avoid. + ______ + + Chairman Miller. Thank you very much to all of you for your +testimony. + Mrs. Bovbjerg, toward the end of your testimony, you said +that one of the problems was that many of the fees are hidden +from sponsors and might mask conflicts of interest. Could you +elaborate? + Ms. Bovbjerg. What we are talking about there is when a +sponsor may contract with a pension consultant or a service +provider, who then has, unknown to the sponsor, a business +relationship with, say, a fund manager, and then recommends to +the sponsor, ``You should use this, you should go with this +fund manager.'' + Chairman Miller. And that may be without regard to +performance or cost? + Ms. Bovbjerg. It may not be in the best interest of the +plan. + Chairman Miller. You also said that the Department of Labor +did not have resources to adequately--fill in the--to do what? +I didn't catch the last part of your testimony there. + Ms. Bovbjerg. Well, the Department of Labor doesn't get the +information that they would need to enforce fee +responsibilities. They don't get a total fee reported to them +in the Form 5500, the primary way that they get information +from plan sponsors. We think that they should make that more +clear, that they need all of the fees in one place. + Chairman Miller. You think that should be corrected? + Ms. Bovbjerg. We have recommended that to them, and they +are pursuing several initiatives in the area. + Chairman Miller. What is the status of that, do you know, +since this report? + Ms. Bovbjerg. Of our recommendation? + Chairman Miller. Yes. + Ms. Bovbjerg. They are considering it. + Chairman Miller. Yes? + Ms. Bovbjerg. They haven't done anything yet, but they are +considering it. + Chairman Miller. Okay, thank you. + The example that you just pointed out, a few months, there +was a story in one of the business journals talking about this +arrangement, where money was between sponsor and a fund. And it +was one of the worst-performing funds and had been one of the +worst-performing funds for multiple years, like among the +worst, and yet they kept paying out money to get, you know, +recommendations of deposits of funds in that fund. + So is that what you are talking about, that kind of +conflict of interest? I am not necessarily saying of that +magnitude, because this was---- + Ms. Bovbjerg. Well, we are talking about some of the things +that came up in the SEC report a couple of years ago. They +looked at 24 pension consultants and found that about half of +them had undisclosed relationships with other types of service +providers. + Now, that is not to say that there was necessarily a +conflict or that it harmed the pension fund, but it was not +disclosed, and they felt that was problematic. + Chairman Miller. Mr. Hutcheson, in your testimony, you +suggest that that is not that unusual. + Mr. Hutcheson. No, sir, that is very common. That is a very +common practice. In some cases, the term ``directed +brokerage,'' which is now a banned practice with mutual funds, +an explanation of that is where a fund manager would speak with +a brokerage firm and say, ``I will bring all of the trades of +the underlying securities of our mutual fund to you if you will +then recommend my fund to your sales force.'' + And what would happen is, is the sales force would get a +recommendation for a particular fund, and they would go out and +sell it to plan sponsors. + Chairman Miller. That is a now banned practice, you are +saying? + Mr. Hutcheson. In mutual funds, it is. + Chairman Miller. In mutual funds. + Mr. Hutcheson. There are some other types of investment +pools, where it is not a banned practice, but the egregious +problems happened in mutual funds, and now that is a banned +practice. + Chairman Miller. Thank you. + Mr. Chambers, you suggested that people think that Toyota +builds cars, but they assemble them. But at the end of the day, +they are buying a car which can be--is rated over time. People +say that this is what it costs to drive this car for this year, +this is the maintenance, this is the miles per gallon, and all +the rest of it. + They can find out information and make a decision between +that Toyota and the Chevrolet Impala, if they want. They can +make that decision. My concern is here is that people are being +asked to make decisions or decisions are made for them, and the +assumption is that that is better or that is different. + Because what we see is that, you know, day in and day out, +it is very hard for fund managers to beat the S&P index, right? + Mr. Chambers. If you would elaborate on a particular fund-- +-- + Chairman Miller [continuing]. Mr. Hutcheson's testimony, I +think it was--it is obviously used many times by index funds. +But, for example, the S&P 500 index consistently outperformed +98 percent of the fund managers over 3 years, 97 percent over +10 years, and 94 percent over the past 30 years. + Recent studies reveal--and many more continue to +substantiate--that the passive 60 percent stock, 40 percent +bond portfolio outperformed 90 percent of the largest corporate +pension plan portfolios, ``run by the world's best and +brightest investment minds.'' + Mr. Chambers. And the source for that, sir? + Chairman Miller. It is in Mr. Hutcheson's testimony, but we +see this remark all of the time at the end of the year or the +quarter, where they match and compare actively managed funds +against index funds and other such funds. And it is very hard +for those managers to beat those index over any period of time. + Mr. Chambers. Well, I think, in given periods, you are +absolutely right. + Chairman Miller. Well, 10 years. + Mr. Chambers. But I also think--and if I may, I also +think---- + Chairman Miller. Thirty years is a pretty good given +period, since that is the time most people work. + Mr. Chambers. Possibly. It depends upon which fund it is, +of course. I can tell you, for example, that the funds---- + Chairman Miller. Well, it beats 94 percent of the active +funds, so you can pick the other 6 percent of the funds, and I +hope I could find them. + Mr. Chambers. Well, I can tell you, sir, that, for example, +in our retirement plan, at our law firm, we get this +information every quarter. And over 5 years, which is a +measurement--our law firm has not been in existence for 30 +years, so we don't have that information. + But over the last 5 years, we have outperformed--if you +take all of the funds that we make available, about 10 funds, +we have outperformed the appropriate market index for each one +of those funds an average of 3.05 percent over 5 years. + Do I think that--and if you take a look at the peer +performance reviews of the investment managers who we retained +and the funds that we retain, they are not necessarily in the +top 5 percent or 10 percent of their peer group every year. I +think it depends upon the way that you are looking at the +statistics. + I don't know that I necessarily agree with Mr. Hutcheson's +statistics, not knowing what his basis is. + Chairman Miller. I would say that Mr. Hutcheson is one of +among many--and I am not vouching for his statistic, I am just +saying that this is a comparison that is made in every economic +journal at the end of every quarter and the end of every year, +when they put in a special section on mutual funds, and they +compare how it is done. + Mr. Butler, I don't know if you want to chime in on this, +but---- + Mr. Butler. Well, I would just refer to the Stanford +professors about 30 years ago who threw darts at the Wall +Street Journal and proved that a randomly selected group of +stocks would beat 85 percent of all efforts to manage money +over any rolling 10-year period of time. + It led to five different Nobel Prizes for research coming +out of that original dart-throwing exercise. So I think it is +pretty well-established that, at the end of the day, low fees +are the primary determinant factor for investment results that +are optimal. + Chairman Miller. If I might, I would just like to take one +minute of the committee's time here. The question here, I +think, is the transparency and information available and the +value of that. And, you know, you have what we get in our TSP, +the Thrift Savings Plan, in a relatively simple form at the +very bottom, it has cost to participant. And it is fixed basis +points across all of the funds, except for the L funds, and +those are variable funds, so, as of this date, that was not +available to them. + You have the vanguard approach, which is, again, a one- +page, very simply laid out cost to this. And this is to the +plan, not to the participant. This is to the plan. And then you +have what, I believe, that ING reached an agreement with +Attorney General Spitzer on this, where you have to charge--one +is the end-year balance without fees, end-of-year balance after +the fees. + So I don't know whether these are the right things to do or +not, but the point is, there does appear that there can be a +simplification of explanations, both to plans and to the +participants, in those plans. And that is the quest of this +committee, to see whether or not some of these might make +sense, in terms of helping the participants and the plans make +these decisions. + And with that, I will yield to Mr. McKeon. + Mr. McKeon. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Ms. Bovbjerg, in the colloquy that you had with the +chairman, you talked about the Department of Labor has received +input, and you don't know where they are in the process of +coming out with regulations or proposals? + Ms. Bovbjerg. Well, they have three initiatives in process +right now. And I believe that they told us that the regs would +be forthcoming later this year. They have been collecting a lot +of comments on those initiatives. + Our recommendation to them was a little different than +those initiatives. We would have recommended that they require +sponsors to provide a total of the fees associated with the +plan by type, in the Form 5500, and they have not taken action +on that yet, but they also hadn't said they wouldn't. They are +considering it. + Mr. McKeon. How much do you think could be done by the +Department of Labor, versus what we should try to do in +legislation? + Ms. Bovbjerg. Well, some things, for example, with regard +to the 5500, can be done by regulations in the Department of +Labor. Other things, you are so right, have to be done through +statute. + We had recommended in our recent report on fees a couple of +things that Congress might consider. Both would require +amendments to ERISA. One was to require service providers to +provide information on their financial relationships to +sponsors. And the other--and that would be an explicit +requirement. Now it is not a requirement. Some sponsors know; +some sponsors don't. + And another would be to require sponsors to provide +participants information on fees that would allow them to make +comparisons across funds. + Mr. McKeon. It sounds to me like all of you are in +agreement that something should be done for disclosure +simplification. + Ms. Bovbjerg. I think we are. + Mr. McKeon. Well, that is what I heard in the testimony. +The concern I have is one that I addressed in my opening +statement, is unintended consequences. And how do you simplify +without making it much more complicated? + It seems like every time we try to simplify--not our +committee, but the Ways and Means, when they try to simplify +the tax code, pages upon pages are added to the tax code. And +that is a concern I have. + The prospectus that the chairman showed--well, they are all +familiar with them, as we are. They are very complicated. I +have bought stocks for my life, and I am sorry to admit that I +usually don't read every word in those things. And it would be +nice to have a little summary or something to go with them, but +a lot of that is a result of laws that have been passed or +regulations. + So I am really sympathetic to the need to simplify. I am +just concerned of, once we start trying to simplify, what we +end up with at the end of the road. You know, if we sat down +with these four people in a room--a few of us--we could +probably work something out that would be good and be +profitable. And I am concerned as we move forward that we just +don't make things worse at the end of the day. + So, Mr. Chairman, what I would like to ask all of them and +others, as we go through this process, to keep involved. And if +you will watch where we are skewing things one way or another, +please try to bring it back. I don't know if you are planning +on moving forward with legislation on this, but that would be +my big concern, is that we---- + Chairman Miller. I am thinking about it now. + Ms. Bovbjerg. Could I chime in for a minute? I perceive +that part of it is the concern about not overburdening +sponsors, and another part is the concern about plain English, +which is something that we at GAO worry about across a lot of +different programs, and something that the Social Security +Administration has to worry about, with the benefit statements +they send out to a much wider ranger of Americans than people +who actually have pensions. + It is something that I think any disclosure of initiatives +that we as a government take in this area, we might consider +some language about plain English, making it accessible. + Mr. McKeon. Like the things that the chairman just showed, +I think were good, simple. The problem is, we pass laws, the +president signs the law, regulators write what they think that +we meant when we passed the law. And by the time it all gets +done, plain English is totally gone. + And, I mean, we did that--when we go to the doctor's now, +we all have to sign a new form. And I am a little chagrined +every time I go in the doctor's office and have to sign that, +because it was federal legislation that required that. And it +just gets put somewhere in a file, nobody ever reads it, nobody +ever does anything with it, but it just was a result of some +legislation. + So I would be happy to join with you, if you think that is +an approach---- + Chairman Miller. I appreciate the comments. I hadn't smoked +out what we would do yet. I would like to think about it. But +when I read much of this testimony, it along with the GAO and +its make a fairly compelling case that inaction is probably not +an option for the committee. + And I appreciate your concerns and your willingness to work +on this and to, certainly, use these witnesses as resources. + And we always know that, when the law leaves here, it is +clearly written, so it is not open to ambiguous interpretation. +But we know we can start with a clear statement of purpose. + Mr. Kildee? + Mr. Kildee. I will be brief. I think we have a vote on the +floor. + But, Mr. Butler, what do you think it would take to get the +401(k) industry to move towards a simple, one-page fee +disclosure that captures all the fees? + Mr. Butler. Well, I think it would be very simple. First of +all, you have to appreciate that the entire industry today +operates in a seamless, electronic environment. So those of us +who are actually keeping track of this money--I won't make it +too absurdly simple, but I would almost say that, with a few +keystrokes, we can determine what the actual costs are and +report them very effectively. + I see it being a de minimis additional effort and probably +not something that would increase costs in any way. + Mr. Kildee. You think it is not rocket science to do? + Mr. Butler. It is not rocket science. + Mr. Hutcheson. Could I, Congressman Kildee? I agree. I +believe that the solution is very simple. I believe in letting +the markets work and letting competition drive prices. And I do +not believe that this would impair, or impede, or discourage +employers from maintaining plans. I believe that it would +greatly increase confidence in letting that competition go, +unencumbered and unimpeded. + And I just wanted to share and elaborate on something. +William Sharpe, who won the Nobel Prize in Economics, said that +the market generally is supposed to be efficient. And when you +start actively managing investments, whether at the mutual fund +level, or at the plan level, or at the sub-plan level, the +participants level, the fees start to be added, and there is a +direct correlation, an exact correlation between the returns of +what the participants receive and the costs. + So active-managed funds and index funds are the same before +costs. You add costs and fees, and there becomes the disparity. + And what happens is, is that when a participant receives +their participant statement, they show that their funds and +their plan are meeting the benchmarks or matching this index or +that index, but that is for the fund. That is for the fund +itself. + Those statements do not show what that particular +participant's return was. And that has to be corrected, +because, with all due respect, a good-manned firm may have +great performing funds at the fund level, but once you start +adding in various costs, the actual participant returns are +very different. And that is an important clarification that I +wanted to make. + But coming back to this, I believe strongly that it is +simple. If we strip out all the ambiguity, all the obscurity, +and let the market work based on fully transparent, fully +disclosed information, the fees will go down. There will be +good competition. There will be confidence in the system. + Plan sponsors will appreciate it. I don't see plan sponsors +bailing out of this. I see them embracing this. And it is in +the best interest of American business to shore up the economic +security of its workforce, because 20 years from now, we have +got a big pool of baby boomers who are going to be retired who +won't have enough money to meaningfully participate in the +economy. + And a lot of businesses are going to wonder why they are +struggling. It is because a whole segment of the economy was +removed because they didn't have enough money. There is no +money to spend. + And so it behooves plan sponsors to deal with this. It is +in everybody's interests. + Mr. Kildee. And they are going to be in the 401(k)-type +rather than the defined benefit-type, so we have a large number +of people who will be affected by this then. + Mr. Hutcheson. That is correct. + Mr. Kildee. Ms. Bovbjerg, can we learn anything from the +Thrift Savings Plan that we have in the federal government that +can help us in the 401(k)s? + Ms. Bovbjerg. The Thrift Savings Plan discloses information +in a clear way, as Chairman Miller was showing. I think it is +important to remember that the Thrift Savings Plan is somewhat +different from 401(k)s, in that their administrative costs are +exceedingly low compared to other forms of--you know, other +types of plans, that some of that has to do with the way that +that plan is administered throughout the government. + It also has to do with--they have been very effective in +keeping their costs low, I have to acknowledge that. I just +think it is difficult to make that comparison, because you are +dealing with a less diverse group of people. We are dealing +with federal employees. They can all read; they all speak +English. You know, it is quite different than a much broader +type of plan coverage. + Mr. Kildee. Thank you very much. + Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Mr. Boustany. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + We would all agree that disclosure and transparency are +very good things. Mr. Chambers, is there a danger in +oversimplifying, when providing information to participants, +that could lead to poor choices? Could you elaborate on that +and what sort of problems that that might create? + Mr. Chambers. Surely, thank you. + Despite some of the comments that have been made earlier +today about fees being the most important--and, perhaps--I am +not suggesting anyone has said the only important, but the most +important factor here--a large number, certainly in my +experience, the predominant number of financial advisers have +indicated that there are many different things that should be +put into focus as you are making an investment decision. +Clearly, fees are one of them. + The gentleman to my right, Mr. Hutcheson, I think just +mentioned the fact that, you know, you look at total return. +That is generally going to be net of some fees, perhaps all +fees, depending upon what is being paid out of the funds. + Risk is an issue. Diversification is an issue. There are +many, many issues that need to go into an investment decision. +Perhaps that is why Mr. McKeon is no longer investing in +stocks, because of all of the different things that you have to +consider when you are making an investment decision. + So I think that the big problem with oversimplification +here is an overemphasis on fees. Yes, they are important. Yes, +they should generally be disclosed. But they can--just looking +at that and that alone can lead to some very bad investment +decisions. + Mr. Boustany. I thank you for that answer. + Ms. Bovbjerg, in looking at ERISA, Section 404, could you +basically state what it requires and what was its intended +purpose? And in the view of GAO, is it really meeting that +purpose? + Ms. Bovbjerg. I don't know if I can do all that right here +and now. I can talk a little about 404(c), which is +particularly relevant---- + Mr. Boustany. 404(c) is particular, yes. + Ms. Bovbjerg [continuing]. To this topic, that plans that +fall under 404(c) are essentially seeking freedom from +liability for investment choices that the participants make. In +return, they have to disclose certain things beyond what other +plans would have to do. + We had a little trouble trying to figure out what +proportion 401(k)s sell under 404(c). We thought it was 50 +percent to 60 percent, somewhere in there. Those are the plans +that the Labor Department is thinking about focusing new fee +reporting requirements on. + Now, the way we see some of the fee reporting, it is all +over. It is effective in some plans, but not uniformly. +Participants have to ask for certain things; they have to know +to ask for certain things; they have to pull information from +several different sources. + You know, and 404(c) plans, it is easier to get that +information, no question about it. But is it complete? It is +just not clear to us that it is. + Mr. Boustany. I thank you. + I yield back. + Chairman Miller. Mr. Yarmouth? + Mr. Yarmuth. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + I only have one question, and I think I know the question, +but it seems like there is nothing to prohibit any of the +providers from disclosing their fee structure. And my question +is--and anyone can address is--why is unreasonable that this +wouldn't become a huge competitive advantage, in what is +apparently a pretty competitive field, 700,000 plans out there? + Why couldn't we allow--just allow the markets, the +providers to use that as their advantage? The lowest fee +structure, if they advertised it, would give them a competitive +advantage. + Mr. Hutcheson. If I might, thank you for that question. + The reason--and I will try not to be too complicated here, +or complex, rather--401(k) are today governed partially in a +fiduciary environment, as they were originally intended and +contemplated, and partially in a non-fiduciary environment. +They are exemptions that exist that permit non-fiduciary +investment firms and others to participate in 401(k) plans, +where otherwise they might have been prohibited from doing so, +had the exemption not been given. + And so this intermingling or blending of non-fiduciary and +fiduciary philosophies is the root cause of this. And if you +bifurcate the two, fiduciary standards of care demand +transparency and open competition based on equal information +between the buyer and the seller. + It is the non-fiduciary component of 401(k) plans that is +obscuring this, partially due to that exemption or to +exemptions. And when I say ``that exemption,'' I am referring +to the Merrill exemption that permits them to participate in +401(k) plans and receive various forms of compensation without +being held to a fiduciary standard. + And if we help everybody to a fiduciary standard, this +might self-correct. + Mr. Yarmuth. Can I just ask for clarification? Do I +understand you correctly that what you are saying is that +different providers have different obligations under these +plans, and therefore the fees wouldn't be apples to apples? + Mr. Hutcheson. Exactly. You can take two physicians' +offices. Both of them have 20 employees. One of them has +service providers that acknowledge their fiduciary status and +behave as such. The other physician's office has the exact same +mutual funds, or funds, but yet their service providers are +hiding behind an exemption that protects them from fiduciary +responsibility. + And, therefore, they are not held to the same standards of +disclosure, and that has to be eradicated from the 401(k) +system. I believe that it will self-correct if that happens. + Mr. Chambers. My experience is that, although certainly +there are some folks who will perform a service as a fiduciary +and others who will perform the same service as a non- +fiduciary, is that I don't see any less disclosure of fees in +one situation, as opposed to the other. + And, clearly, plan sponsors, if they wish to off-load +fiduciary status onto someone rather than retaining it +themselves, they certainly have the capacity and the +marketplace to do that. As Mr. Hutcheson just pointed out, +there are organizations out there who will accept this role. + There are other organizations, though, that say, ``I will +do it in a different fashion,'' and that is the marketplace. +There is a decision. I don't believe that in under any +circumstances do you need to homogenize that, do you need to +invariably go out and find someone who is willing to serve as a +fiduciary to perform the function to the exclusion of someone +who is not, particularly for purposes of this hearing, if both +of them are charging relatively the same fee or, even if they +are not, if they are disclosing it. + Mr. Hutcheson. If I may just clarify, because 401(k) plans +are a fiduciary animal, they are subject to trust laws. And +trust laws have fiduciaries. And fiduciaries must be able to +discharge their duties unimpeded. They must not have obscured +information or they must not have information withheld. + Let me give you a specific example. I was asked by the +chairman of an organization to come in and explain how their +investment providers are managing their fee for free. Well, +clearly, that can't be the case, but that is what the chairman +was told. And we are talking about $100 million plan. + And I categorically and summarily disagree absolutely. The +fiduciaries simply didn't know what the pay or cost structure +was of the plan. None only does ERISA demand that fiduciaries +know, but if fiduciaries don't really understand whose getting +paid, then they can't discharge their duties. + And they are withholding information, because they are not +held to a fiduciary standard. And I believe strongly that they +should be. + Mr. Butler. If I may, as a further answer---- + Mr. Yarmuth. I think I am glad I asked this question. + Mr. Butler. Pardon me? + Mr. Yarmuth. I think I am glad I asked this question. + Mr. Butler. Well, what I would like to do is just elaborate +and talk about money for a minute, as opposed to fiduciaries. +Mr. Chambers, in his written testimony, presented an elegant, +perfect example of how fees are charged. + He used as an example $150 for the total cost of operating +a plan for, say, a participant; $50 of that cost would be for +the actual administration of the plan, $100 would be for the +money management portion. + And then he pointed out that, on the $100 of the money +management portion, which is going to the mutual fund, they are +going to give up or pay $10 of it back to the company doing the +administration. So the administration company is actually +getting $60, and the mutual fund company is getting a net of +$90. + In the real world, you can expand that to a real situation. +Let's say that we have a $10 million plan. It has 150 +employees, probably an engineering firm, a law firm, company +that has been around for at least 15 to 20 years. And so now, +instead of $150, we have actually 1.5 percent, which would be +pretty typical, $150,000 is what is now being paid, one way or +the other, to administer this plan of $10 million. + We have got $100,000 going to the mutual fund. They are +giving up $10,000 of it and paying it to the record-keeper. +Somebody understanding that there is that breakdown of cost +could now start shopping for the record-keeping services. And +on this particular plan, they would be able to get those +services for something in the neighborhood of roughly $10,000 a +year. They don't need to pay $50,000. + The $10,000 for the record-keeping is really for the +seamless electronic environment that allows people to dial up +their account on the Internet, and that is a basic commodity in +the industry today. + So now you have a plan sponsor who has an opportunity +possibly to save his participants about $40,000. And at this +point, he is now looking at the other component of the plan, +which is the mutual fund company that is charging $90,000. And +a person confronted with that information is going to say to +himself, ``Maybe I can get this money managed for something +closer to $40,000, instead of $90,000,'' and he could. + So now he is just saved his participants, including +himself, because he has his own account to think about, he +saved himself and his participants about 1 full percentage +point per year. The magic of compound interest works against us +when we start taking fees or paying fees out of money that +could otherwise be compounding, tax-deferred. + It is counterintuitive. In this particular example, let's +say we have saved about--we have increased our returns by about +10 percent, let's say. So you ask yourself, ``Well, why is that +leading to 20 percent more money downstream?'' And the answer +to that is, because that additional 1 percent compounded adds +up to 20 percent of the total account balance. + He has essentially saved his participants 20 percent of +what they otherwise would have spent, and effectively he has +increased everybody's retirement nest egg by 25 percent. And +that is what this is really all about; that is why these +hearings are so important. + Chairman Miller. The gentleman's time has expired. + Mr. Kline? + Thank you for the question. + Mr. Kline. Well, I am going to let us continue down that +line. It looked like Mr. Chambers wanted to have something to +say. I would like you to do that, and then I would like to +address my question. + Mr. Chambers. Thank you, sir. + The point that I was going to make is, that that is exactly +the problem that I have highlighted. Mathematically, that makes +great sense. But should the employer or whoever it is who is +making the decision on who is going to be investing plan assets +or whose products will be available, who is going to be +administering the plan, that they should do that, either solely +on the basis of fees or largely on the basis of fees? + There was no indication here about what the relative +performance of the two record-keeper. Does the record-keeper, +does the new program permit all the bells and whistles that the +employer and the employees want? That costs money. Does the +investment adviser, who is being selected, because, in fact, +they charge fewer dollars, you know, per thousand, what is +their relative rate of return over a long period of time? + All of this needs to be put into the perspective of a lot +of different people making decisions on the basis of a lot of +different points. + Thank you. + Mr. Kline. Thank you. I knew you were chomping at the bit +there, so to speak. + I don't know, Mr. Chairman, do the witnesses have this---- + Chairman Miller. I don't know, but we will get it to them. + Mr. Kline. Okay. + Chairman Miller. Yes, it was shown up. Maybe it can be put +back up on the plasma screen. + Mr. Kline. It seems to me like there is some agreement here +in the committee--and maybe throughout the room--that +transparency and visibility into these funds is a useful thing. + But I am concerned that we sometimes do confuse the famous +apples and oranges, and I am just trying to understand. I +think, Ms. Bovbjerg, you were talking about this issue earlier, +not confusing or not trying too hard to compare the Thrift +Savings Plan with some other 401(k)s. + And this, clearly, is doing exactly that. It is comparing +the Thrift Savings Plan with some--I don't know if that is a +real fund, but it shows a significant difference, when you +compare the TSP with this notional 401(k). It looks like those +are dollars per individual. + What I would like you to do is go back where you were a +couple of questioners ago and talk about why it is that the +Thrift Savings Plan comes in at asset-based fees of 0.6 percent +and why it is not. We are a little apples and oranges here when +we try to compare other 401(k)s. Could you do that for us, kind +of pick up where you were? Thank you. + Ms. Bovbjerg. Absolutely. + I think I would also like to say that this is a graph that +is similar in spirit to one that was in our report on fees that +looks at what, if your fees were 1 percent higher over a 20- +year period, what would that mean? It would be about a 17 +percent loss of income, assets. + The Thrift Savings Plan uses administrators across the +federal government to help people sign up to make changes. The +Department of Education has them; the GAO has them; Congress +has them. + Mr. Kline. And these are public employees rather than---- + Ms. Bovbjerg. These are public employees, and they are-- +Congress pays for its office. GAO pays for its personnel office +that has these people in the Department of Education, so---- + Mr. Kline. Thus reducing the costs? + Ms. Bovbjerg. Yes. So the six basis points is not really +what the administrative cost is of the Thrift Savings Plan, but +that is not to take away from the fact that Thrift Savings Plan +is very efficiently run. So the administrative costs are still +pretty low. + Mr. Kline. Okay, thank you. + Yes, Mr. Hutcheson? + Mr. Hutcheson. The underlying investments in the Thrift +Savings Plan are what we call index funds generally. They are +passive funds. You are getting the broad market. + In the private sector, funds very similar to what is in the +Thrift Savings Plan are available to employers. They might be +slightly more expensive, because it is a price based on the +assets in the plan. But what we are seeing here is a perfect +example of what Professor Sharpe, who won the Nobel Prize in +Economics, and also many other people have said. + If you track the broad market as closely as possible, you +will get market returns, and you really, over the long haul, +can't do better than that. + Mr. Kline. Sure, I understand. You are proposing that we +use the index funds. But what I was trying to get at is that +there is--in the fee world, which we are trying to get +visibility in the fees--what is now shown here, was what Ms. +Bovbjerg pointed out--that because the taxpayers are paying, in +some part, for the administration of this, because we have +public employees who are doing part of this work, the Thrift +Savings Plan is not the best apple-to-apple comparison and what +fees are. + Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back. + Chairman Miller. Thank you. + Mr. Wu? + Mr. Wu. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + First, I want to ask the panel--and, Bob, you in +particular--do we have pretty much uniformity of agreement that +disclosure of the various fees is non-objectionable, as long, +as you said, Bob, that it does not drown out other valuable +information, that disclosure of brokerage fees, 12b-1 fees, and +so on and so forth, that all of those disclosures are +appropriate. + Mr. Chambers. Well, I generally agree, but I think that +where the rubber hits the road is going to be in terms of what +fees needed to be disclosed and how we slice and dice the fees +that are out there. + And to go back to one of the points that the chairman made +earlier, and when he was alluding to my Toyota example, when +you go to buy a car, there is not fee disclosure on how much +Toyota paid for the glass, and there is not fee disclosure on +how much Toyota paid for the computer components. There is an +overall fee. + And I agree: There are ways to assess whether that +particular automobile is better than another automobile, +through miles per gallon, you know, performance, which is what +we are talking about here. + So I think that the council's concern--well, the overall +concept is, yes, we are very favorably behind the idea of full +and fair disclosure of fees. But I do think that where we are +going to run into issues is, exactly how are we going to be +slicing and dicing that? Because I don't know that it is +necessarily essential for a plan participant--to mix the two +metaphors now--that a plan participant needs to know how much +the glass costs in the car. + And I can see, for example, that, if you have a large +financial institution which has been empowered through +contract, you know, to perform services for a plan, and if, for +example, that financial institution decides that it is going to +take one of the functions that it is contractually bound to +perform, and to hand it off to one of its affiliate companies, +you know, say it has a captive trust company, for example, I +don't know that that necessarily is something that needs to be +disclosed. That is internal proprietary information. + But by and large, overall fees, yes, we are very much in +favor of that. + Mr. Wu. Yes. And because of the limitations of time, let me +just say that, in contrast to, say, a Toyota, because of the +difficulty of predicting future market performance, because the +market is basically different from being able to calculate the +speed or safety of a car, some of the rear-view mirror things, +if you will, like fees, take on a disproportionately important +role, I would like to be--I would be very interested in hearing +from all the panelists what disclosures you all feel are +important and the best display format for that, so that it is +most useful for investors. + And I would like to ask that question and get that set of +answers over time in writing, because I would like to turn to +Mr. Hutcheson for a second. And I am not sure that this came +out, Matt, in your oral testimony, but in going through your +written testimony last night, there was a recurring theme of +non-fiduciary functions and fiduciary functions and having +those mixed together, and a core problem of mixing those non- +fiduciary and fiduciary functions together. + But as I read the materials, one of the non-fiduciary +functions was actually the investment decisions of the plan's +beneficiary. And I would like to take me through this a little +bit. It is one of the--where you are going with this, if we +take it all the way out with a fiduciary plan, is that we +ultimately get the plan beneficiary off the loop, in terms of +decisionmaking about investment vehicles. + Mr. Hutcheson. That is right. I personally believe--and +just to clarify before I answer the question--that no person +can time the market. I just don't believe it. I think there is +empirical research that shows that there is only a few points +in time each year where the market really takes a big leap +forward, and you have to be in the market at that point in +time. + And so placing decisions in people who have no financial or +economic or investing experience, and not only just placing +investment decisions, but we are talking about trust assets +subject to fiduciary prudence. + So 404(c) says that a participant will not be deemed a +fiduciary to the extent that they are directing these trust +assets, and that is kind of a conflict in fundamental fiduciary +prudence and trust oversight, as we have been accustomed to, +many, many years, decades before 404(c) was enacted. + And very short, I believe that participants play with their +accounts based on recommendations of friends, what they see in +the news. They have the ability to make changes. 404(c) says +that you have to be able to change your allocations quarterly +or more frequently, as the market dictates. Why would they want +to be changing their accounts based on what happens yesterday? + That is not prudent. It makes no economic sense. It is not +based on good, sound investment research or theory. It in +itself, I believe, is bad public policy. And it, in my opinion, +goes contrary to fundamental laws of fiduciary prudence. + Mr. Chambers. May I add one point, please, to that? And +that is--well, actually two points. + One is, I don't think that that is a correct statement of +trust law, number one. It is difficult for someone to be a +trustee for himself or herself. And, therefore, you are not a +fiduciary, which involves acting on behalf on someone else. So +I don't think that that is a correct statement. + Number two, you need to take a look at the program, I +think, that Mr. Hutcheson is proposing. Now, you know, one of +the comments or one of the things that we talk about is the +series of movies that were out a number of years ago, you know, +``Back to the Future.'' + Well, I think that what he is suggesting is the opposite, +which is ``Forward to the Past.'' There is, if you take a look +at what he is suggesting--which is a very viable program for +employers who are so inclined. I am not trying to say that it +is a bad program at all. I don't think that it is particularly +viable in the view of most employers with whom I work. + It is essentially the creation of a television set that +only gets one channel, and it is a channel that, whoever it is +that is putting that set together, is developing. One set of +investments, you know, no loans, no this, no that. + Why would an employee want to make a decision to change an +investment because of what happened yesterday? There may be +something else in his or her life that dictates that. It also +may be that they no longer have confidence in the investments +that they previously made. + Chairman Miller. The gentleman's time is expired. Thank +you. + Mr. Wu. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Chairman Miller. Mr. Andrews? + Mr. Andrews. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + I very much appreciate the witnesses, and I appreciate this +hearing. I view this hearing as a continuation of work that +this committee has done on a bipartisan basis over the last +number of years, reflecting a number of points of consensus. + The first point of consensus is that it is a reality that +individuals are managing their own investment decisions, and I +think there is a consensus that we should not impede that +individual choice or individual freedom. + In the wake of the Enron scandal a few years ago, there +were some discussions of putting legal limitations on choices +people could make in their own 401(k) plans. I, frankly, +opposed those suggestions, and I am glad they are not the law. + The second point of consensus is that people should--we +should facilitate people getting sound investment advice. Now, +there is still significant disagreement over what that means. +There was a compromised reach in the act of 2006. We will +evaluate the efficacy of that compromise and continue the +discussion, but I think it is obviously true that sound +investment advice is better than no investment advice or, +frankly, a lot better than investment advice from an +incompetent source who doesn't know what he or she is talking +about. + The third point of consensus is that we should maximize +transparency so that people making these individual choices +have the widest array of facts in front of them so they can +make the best choices, which leads us to today's discussion, +which is, what should the form and nature of that transparency +include? + I will confess to you, I come to this discussion as an +agnostic. I am very interested in what you think as to how we +can answer that question. But in my simple agnosticism, I would +make the following proposition. + We talk about people buying cars? I think the best example +is someone selling their house. It is the single most important +economic decision most Americans make. And when most Americans +sell their home, they ask one question. They ask two questions, +really: How much am I going to get for the house? What is the +sale price going to be? And how much of the sale price am I +going to get to keep? + I actually practiced real estate law before I did this and +represented hundreds of homebuyers, and they would ask the +realtor how much they were going to get for the home, how much +the contract was going to be for. And they would ask me, as +their attorney, how much they were going to get to keep. + And we have disclosure laws, RESPA, in the real estate +context that tells someone how much of the proceeds they have +to pay to someone else, the real estate commission and other +fees, and how much they get to keep. + I think that is the basis on which we should build this +disclosure. I think we should build it on the proposition--if +my 401(k) were invested, and I got to keep everything, every +dollar earned on that investment decision, how much would that +be? And then how much are we going to get in a net return, +after whatever fees, or contracts, or considerations are paid? + Does anybody disagree with that as a conceptual framework +for approaching this problem? + Okay. Now, I think there is a second category of this +disclosure we also have to think about. And I am not sure +whether the present law covers this or not, and that is the +situation where, to use the analogy, the sale price of my house +is too low because the realtor was conflicted in some way, that +the realtor sold the house to her sister-in-law rather than to +the highest bidder. + Does anyone think that the present ERISA statute does not +prohibit that situation? Does anybody think that the present +statute doesn't prohibit the situation where the person making +some plan decisions is depriving me of the highest price or the +best investment? + Mr. Butler. If I may, I think there are all kinds of +opportunities for that to happen right now, under the current +situation. Forbes magazine talked about the extent to which the +brokerage industry's own mutual funds do very poorly as +investments, comparatively speaking. + And the reason for that is because the brokerage industry's +source of revenue, to a large extent, has to do with trading +commissions. So the mutual funds that they operate, in many +cases, are feeding troughs for their trading operation. And +that is an example that I see in the industry, along the lines +of what you were just talking about. + Mr. Andrews. Okay. Because my time--do you agree with that +conclusion of Mr. Butler or not? + Mr. Butler. Yes, I do. I would say that---- + Mr. Andrews. No, I know you agree. I asked Mr. Chambers if +he agrees with you. + Mr. Chambers. I don't always agree with myself, so I need +to deal with that. + Mr. Andrews. Okay. + Mr. Chambers. Before I respond to that, to respond to your +comment or your question, I am concerned with your using the +word ``best'' in conjunction with what ERISA requires, as +opposed to what is reasonable, which is, in fact, what the +statutory standard is. + Mr. Andrews. Of course, it doesn't require what is +reasonable. It requires what is in the best interests of the +participant party. + Mr. Chambers. Best interest, yes, but not necessarily the +best result. + Mr. Andrews. Okay. You would agree, that is not synonymous +with reasonable, though. If you make a reasonable choice that +is not in the fiduciary interest of your---- + Mr. Chambers. No, but somebody has to act reasonably. And +one of the ways that they have to act reasonably is within the +best interests of the participants and the beneficiaries. + I think that, if everyone had to go around chasing the best +investment results, or if everyone had to go around chasing the +lowest conceivable method of administrative fees, I think that +this would be a very different world. + Mr. Andrews. Of course, that is not what I asked, though. I +asked whether you thought that the statute prohibits someone +making a conflicted or self-interested decision in the +investment context. + Mr. Chambers. I think that, yes, the statute does currently +prohibit that. + Mr. Andrews. Effectively? + Mr. Chambers. Pardon me? + Mr. Andrews. Effectively? Do you think there is any +loopholes in that? + Mr. Chambers. Are there loopholes? I don't know that I +would call this a loophole, but remember that, for example, +employers have issue--every employer that sponsors a plan +invariably has issues about its role as the settlor of the +plan, the sponsor of the plan, versus its role as a fiduciary +of the plan. And that is something that is inherent in +sponsorships. + So I don't know that you would call that a loophole, but +certainly that is something that everyone has to be concerned +about. + Mr. Andrews. My time is expired. I would just ask if Mr. +Hutcheson wanted to respond. + Chairman Miller. Mr. McKeon wanted to tag on---- + Mr. Andrews. Sure, Mr. Chairman, I would yield. + Mr. McKeon. Will the gentleman yield? + In your example, if the realtor brings an offer to me to +sell my house, I can accept or reject it. So I don't see where +that really plays a role, a comparable role. + The first part, where you talked about just final net +return, it sounds great to me. I don't know where---- + Mr. Andrews. Yes, if the gentleman would yield, here is the +analogy of the realtor bringing an offer. Someone has to make a +decision which options to give the plan participant. You could +limit---- + Mr. McKeon. But it all washes out with the net return. + Mr. Andrews. It washes out---- + Chairman Miller. I will take your answer off the air. + Mr. Andrews. Thank you. + Chairman Miller. Mr. Sarbanes? + Mr. Sarbanes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for +holding the hearing. + I have a brief question. In my view, when it comes to +information, there are two ways you can hide the ball. You can +not disclose enough information, or you can disclose so much +that it becomes impossible for the consumer of the information +to sift through it and understand it. You see that happen in +many, many different arenas. + So, Mr. Butler, I wanted to ask you to address this, +because it is not just about more disclosure. It is about +better disclosure. And I feel as though I get plenty of +information on a lot of things that represent ``full +disclosure'' that I can't make heads or tails of. And this is +another arena were that would be the case. + So it is about how you package it. And your index, +obviously, attempts to do that. But if you could just speak to +the pitfalls of too much disclosure or how we package or +present the information in a way that is really constructive +for the consumer. + Mr. Butler. I would love to address that. + First of all, the need to know, from a decisionmaking +standpoint, really centers on the company management people who +are basically charged with deciding what kind of plan and which +vendors they are going to use. That is why my first book was +called ``The Decisionmaker's Guide to 401(k) Plans.'' + The participants really then wind up being the +beneficiaries of hopefully some informed decisionmaking. When +you are looking at the component costs of one of these plans-- +and the example that I was using earlier--what is important is +for these decisionmakers to be able to basically understand +each component cost so that they can effectively decide whether +or not they want to be part of a package deal or not. + And the example that I used, we presupposed that we had +mutual funds and then a separate company, let's say, as a +record-keeper. But, in fact, in about 70 percent of all 401(k) +plans, it is all in the same building. It is the mutual fund +that also has three floors of record-keepers keeping track of +the money and doing the compliance-related issues. + And so the important thing is for this bundled provider to +be able to present to the decisionmakers, their clients, what +the component costs are so that the decisionmakers can decide +whether or not they want to be part of a package deal. Or can +they create a much better opportunity for their participants by +breaking things up and shopping for better opportunities? + It is like, when you buy a car, you might decide that you +don't want the manufacturer's Bose stereo because you can get a +much better deal buying a stereo independently. + Mr. Sarbanes. Do you think that the ``decisionmakers'' can +be as susceptible to getting too much information, as +beneficiaries can, or because they are better versed and this +is their responsibility, to make these decisions, that they are +sort of protected against that? + Mr. Butler. My experience, in the smaller company +environment--and, bear in mind, 70 percent of all Americans +work for companies that have less than 100 employees--my +experience is that decisionmakers in that environment tend to +be the company owners, who are by definition successful +businesspeople, many are self-styled investment experts +themselves, or mutual fund experts. + Also, the CFO or controller will also be part of that de +facto decisionmaking committee. And these people are very, very +sophisticated. They make the right decisions if given the right +information. + Mr. Sarbanes. Thank you. + Mr. Chambers. May I comment? + Mr. Sarbanes. Sure. + Mr. Chambers. I guess I agree with most of what Mr. Butler +just said. The one issue that I have is, that I am not sure +that it is appropriate or essential to get a bundled provider +to explain what the cost allocation is or the expense +allocation is, if it is not making those services available +independent of one another. + In other words, the way--and I just went through this with +a client--that is a small employer, about 100, 150 employees, +and they wanted to look at new record-keeping investment +systems. And they went to some programs that were bundled, and +we found out what the total costs were from that. And then they +went to other programs which were not bundled, and we found out +what the total costs were there. + I don't know that it would be essential to receive +information from the bundled program, for example, about how +much it was allocating to provide record-keeping, as opposed to +some other component, if that is not available from that same +organization. I don't know that that is information that is +going to help you to make a meaningful decision. + Mr. Sarbanes. Well, I hear that, and I worry--it is a fair +point, although it could also be the beginning of a slide, kind +of slippery slope, in terms of what comparative information is +available. + I yield back. Thanks. + Ms. Shea-Porter. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + I can remember when the fees for banking and mortgages were +so absolutely confusing, and there has been some streamlining. +And probably my son, who is 17, is the only one who still pays +10 percent monthly on his balance at a bank, and we are going +to straighten that out. + But the reason I brought that up was because it is +difficult for people who are not knowledgeable to understand. +And it is pretty clear on the bank statements to me now, you +know, what the fees will be. And I will be teaching my 17-year- +old shortly the same thing. + But when you try to compare different plans, I think there +is an obligation--this actually is to Ms. Bovbjerg--an +obligation to be as explicit as possible. And I think it is +possible to be simple, as well, when you are explaining the +fees. + And I listened to my colleague talk about the costs of the +TSP, for example, and I wanted to ask you to address that. He +said that federal employees were picking up some of the cost of +the administration. Do you have any idea how much the federal +employees are actually picking up? And is it possible to +compare those two plans? + I am fortunate enough to be in the TSP, and it is clear, +and the administrative fees are lower. So could you address +that, please? + Ms. Bovbjerg. And you have touched on one of the reasons +that makes it so difficult to compare the Thrift Savings Plan +to other types of retirement saving vehicles. + When I brought up the thing about the Thrift Savings Plan, +I did want to say that, you know, this graph is essentially +showing the math between two things. And the math is correct, +but it is the implication that six basis points is sort of +normal I was a little concerned about. + The Thrift Savings Plan has certain levels of expenses. +And, in fact, we will be reporting on these costs for +Congressman Davis in a couple of months. But the Thrift Savings +Plan does take its--gets revenue from not only, you know, from +not having to do things, but also from the money that is what I +would call ``left on the table,'' you know, the federal +government matches and puts in 1 percent. + And for people who come to the federal government, the +people who leave before they invest, can only take their money, +and they leave the federal money on the table. That also nets +the administrative costs for the TSP. That is one of the +reasons why they look so low. + I would like to say that, in terms of reporting to +individuals, it is critical that it be simple, that it be +clear, it be all in one place, and that people don't have to go +ask for it, because they will never find it. Only a certain +percentage of people will know to do that. + But it is hard. It is hard for the Social Security +Administration to produce a benefits statement that 270 million +Americans can understand. And they put a lot of effort into it. +So I don't want to discount what I know are the concerns about, +how do you really make something that people will find +accessible? It is not easy, but it is important. + Ms. Shea-Porter. Right, but it is doable, that is what you +are saying. + Ms. Bovbjerg. It is doable. + Ms. Shea-Porter. Right, and still leave a healthy profit +for those who are the administrators. + Ms. Bovbjerg. I can't say what it would cost, different +kinds of sponsors. And, certainly, I know that the Department +of Labor is weighing, you know, sponsor burden against the +outcome and trying to figure out how they can best achieve some +sort of optimal result. + Ms. Shea-Porter. Okay, thank you. + Chairman Miller. Thank you very much. + And thank you for all of your testimony. + A couple of things here. One is, I guess the question I +would ask--and I appreciate Mr. Andrews raising the point, if +you had a net-net-net figure, would that tell you what you +really need to know as a consumer, or would these other +packages of information be more informative, or what have you? +And that is obviously to be discussed further. + But the real question for me is, again, a lot of people-- +you know, you can have $100 million plan, and a lot of people +are struggling to put in $6,000, $7,000 into this plan. And +they don't have a lot of room for risk and fees and the rest of +this. + And the question that I would raise is, are we sure that we +are getting the value added for that? And is there a reasonable +reason why somebody made a decision to go in that direction? Or +was it a conflicted decision? Or was it a decision that really +didn't meet that reasonableness when you consider who is in the +plan? + You know, the Miller family doesn't have a lot of margin of +error for mistakes. My employer apparently does, because we +have got $1 trillion debt he is running around with. But, you +know, the sponsor of this plan, the owner of the business, and +maybe the officers, depending on the size of it, they may have +a lot of income. People working for them may have reasonable +income or good income. But good income today doesn't give you a +lot of room for risk. + So, you know, the question is, how does that factor in? And +I guess the disappointment I see is that you have a lot of +people dipping into other people's money. You know, I didn't +put the money into the 401(k) plan so a lot of strangers could +come in and start dipping into this, under manufactured titles, +for fees of questionable services, whether I need them or not +need them. + Now, I am an individual, and so then we have to go to the +plan, we have to go to the sponsors, and I think that is the +central question for me, that this really is about other +people's monies. And I think that, also, you are in an +atmosphere where people have determined--maybe it is the advent +of the Internet--but if you can charge a real small fee a +billion times, you can become a really rich company. And people +say, ``Oh, that fee doesn't matter.'' + Well, as we have seen, every one of you have given us a +comparison chart of what it would mean--let's just use the 1 +percent differential. That is a lot of money to a middle-class +working American, at the end of the time, when they think they +are going to retirement, and what are they going to be able to +extract if they don't want to eat up the principal of that nest +egg? + Those are big differences. One of you said that the +difference was the--between the 1 percent and 1.5 percent, 1.5 +percent differential, the person who was on the bad end of that +bargain would have to work an additional 7 years. I mean, these +are big consequences to workers and to families. + And I guess my concern--I mean, one of the things discussed +with the members of the committee and with others, is the +question really, are they getting value added here? + You know, I have listened to I don't know how many +financial shows over 20 years, where one side is saying, ``This +should be the position for most American investors, an index +fund. It is safe, it is low cost, and the rest of that.'' + And the other people say, ``Oh, no, you can go out there, +and you can beat the market,'' and there is a lot of reasons +why people say that, because they are out there trying to beat +the market, and they need clients to do so. And that may be +good for some people, but it may not be good for this plan that +is becoming a larger and larger percentage of people's +retirement. + This isn't their mad money; this is their retirement. By +default, this has become one of the two remaining legs on the +retirement stool in this. + You know, we have been talking about a comparison of the +thrift plan, but I think IBM and Xerox are even more efficient +in these 401(k) plans than the thrift. Does anybody have any +knowledge of that, that they--one of you had it in your +statement, I am sorry. + Mr. Butler. My understanding is that Xerox charges .03 +percent to their employees. They probably have some other +costs, but they are paying those costs as a tax-deductible +corporate business expense, instead of having participants pay +it with money that would otherwise be compounding tax-free. + Chairman Miller. That is because of a separate decision +they made, how they would allocate the costs. So that is a +benefit, I guess, that you would argue they feel strongly +enough financially to be able to shift. + Mr. Butler. Exactly. And there is no way that Xerox would +then be paying 100 basis points as a corporate business +expense. They have just figured out what the fixed cost is for +each participant in the plan, and it is probably about $50 a +year to keep track of the money, per person. + Chairman Miller [continuing]. Xerox is not a small +business, with, you know, 100, 150 employees. So there is some +bargaining---- + Mr. Chambers. I think you need to look at it as an employer +contribution to the plan. And Xerox could ask the employees to +pay whatever the amount is and be providing a larger employer +contribution in the form of a match or, perhaps, in a profit- +sharing contribution. And the employees would be in the same +position. + So I think that you are correct, but there is another way +to do it, which is the way that a lot of employers are doing +it. + Mr. Hutcheson. Chairman Miller, I don't think that anybody +is suggesting radical open-heart surgery. I think what we are +suggesting is, is asking that plans be governed by prudent +fiduciaries in possession of full and correct information. Once +they are in possession of all the information, if they want +bells and whistles, and the fiduciaries certainly have the +discretion to purchase them on behalf of the participants and +beneficiaries to whom they serve. + Without full information, the fiduciaries are impeded. And +if we have a seller and a fully informed buyer, the free market +system will take care of this. But as it is today, the +purchasers of retirement services do not understand, not even +the Department of Labor fully understands what the nature of +the economics are or is. + And, thus, we have a situation. That is what needs to be +remedies. We need to empower the fiduciaries with correct, full +information, and let knowledgeable fiduciaries and the +knowledgeable deliverers of services negotiate on equal +standing. + Mr. Chambers. I don't disagree with that at all. I think we +need to maintain confidence in this system. I think we need to +improve confidence in this system. + And I think that, again, all of us on the panel agree that +there needs to be another methodology of providing this +information to all three of the constituencies that we have +been discussing, participants, and the fiduciaries, and the +government, in order to pursue this. I don't disagree with that +at all. + But I think it is important to make sure, as I have +mentioned before, that the cost of doing this is not going to +overwhelm the benefit that comes from it, that, in fact, we +wind up not diminishing end-of-the-road retirement benefits, +simply because we have overemphasized fees, compared to all of +the other important considerations that go into the +administration of these plans and the investment of their +assets. + Chairman Miller. Should the plan sponsor know whether or +not there is conflicting financial arrangements for the +placement of those funds? + Mr. Chambers. I think that the plan sponsor needs to +understand what the relationships are. And I think, then, that +the plan sponsor needs to make a decision as to whether there +is a conflict there, whether the conflict is---- + Chairman Miller. So they should have the information? You +would agree that they should have the information? + Mr. Chambers. I think that they need to have information +relating to what the role of each service provider is. And then +they can decide whether or not there is a conflict. + One of the issues that are out there is that you may have a +service provider that has a relationship at this end of the +spectrum with a financial organization, and you have entirely +independent people working at that plan level. So the question +is, is there a conflict? + There may be a conflict in an entirely unrelated area. Does +the administrator or the plan sponsor need to know that? I +think it would be very helpful, but I am not sure that in every +situation you are going to be able to provide that information. + Ms. Bovbjerg. Which is why recommended the Congress amend +ERISA to explicitly require service providers to provide that +information to plan sponsors. + Chairman Miller. If ``A'' is placing their funds with +``B,'' and ``B'' is getting money from ``C,'' that in itself is +an important piece of information. + Mr. Chambers. Right. How about if a bank is a lender to a +particular organization, you know, is a primary lender or is +involved--that is why I am saying---- + Chairman Miller. Well, with all due respect, you know, +those questions are answered every day in the courtrooms of +this country, because among the biggest players in this field, +they are suing one another over exactly those relationships. + We just saw a whole series of arrangements in the mutual +fund industry, 3, 4, 5 years ago, where all kinds of privileges +were extended based upon other arrangements. People were +allowed to trade after 4 o'clock. People were allowed to not +mark to market. People were allowed to go over until the next +day. + You know, and they were based upon loans and placements of +funds. I mean, that goes on in the financial services industry +every day. Big clients get privileges, and connected people get +privileges. So this goes on all the time. + The question is, you know, my little firm, and I am trying +to take care of my employees, should I know whether the person +I am working with has these financial relationships? I will +then make a decision about whether I think that is impacting or +not impacting, or it may come back to me a year later when I +see what happens. I may say, ``Whoa, whoa, let's go back and +see what that relationship was.'' + Mr. Chambers. I believe, sir, that if you are limiting this +primarily to the retirement plan context, I think, then, that +it would be possible to come up with a reasonable way of +creating disclosure that is beneficial. + But as I was mentioning, I think it is very difficult--if I +decide that I want to go to a bank to serve as the trustee of +my retirement plan, and it turns out that that bank is the +primary lender to an organization that is providing retirement +services to me, all right, is that a conflict? And how is it +that somebody is supposed to be disclosing that too me? + Chairman Miller. That may or may not be. Again, when people +look back over transactions, very often they all of a sudden +recognize a conflict that they didn't recognize at the time. So +the information is important. + It has been very important to the SEC. It has been very +important to states' attorneys generals and to others, because +patterns do develop. We just saw a pattern develop of inside +trading. There, the enforcement officers recognized it for the +investment firm, and then they decided they would cut +themselves in on it. You know, we just went through the arrest +here this last week. + So the information is important, not only at the time you +can make your judgment, whether you think that is right or +wrong; it may be important down the road, if a pattern develops +or these people have relationships. You know, it may not be +about your fund, but it may be about all of the investors that +come there and the fund they go to. + You may be part of a larger piece of action. That is all I +am saying. So I just am asking whether or not that arrangement, +in and of itself, should be a piece of information that is +available. I am not determining whether it is a conflict or not +a conflict, simply whether that disclosure is important. + And most of these things that concern me about little +people, it is because I see the big guys fighting it out. You +know, they are battling over their pension plans, very large +corporations, because somebody decided they were going to dip +their hand into other people's money, with an insignificant +fee, and they could drain it off. + I mean, that is sort of the nature of financial abuse in +the financial services industry. People come up with these +schemes sort of, you know, every full moon. + Any other questions? + [Additional statements for the record follow:] + [The prepared statement of Mr. Altmire follows:] + +Prepared Statement of Hon. Jason Altmire, a Representative in Congress + From the State of Pennsylvania + + Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for holding this important hearing on +``Hidden 401(k) Fees,'' and for your continued leadership on issues of +great importance to America's working families. + I would like to extend a warm welcome to today's witnesses. I thank +all of you for taking the time to be here and look forward to hearing +from you. + In recent years, 401 (k) plans have emerged as the most common way +for Americans to save for their retirement. Currently, nearly 50 +million employees are enrolled in 401(k) plans as compared to +approximately 20 million employees who are enrolled in traditional +pension plans. With the rise of the number of employees using 401 (k) +plans to prepare for their retirement, we must work to ensure that +their plans operate as efficiently as possible. + Many have raised concerns about the operation of 401(k) plans. The +most common complaint is that administrative and management fees for +401 (k) plans are not clearly defined and delineated. Many of these +fees nickel and dime the retirement savings of employees who may not +even be aware of their existence. I share these concerns and believe +that these fees should be properly disclosed, rather than simply +deducted from the account balances of employees. + I also believe that we should do more to encourage employees to +invest in 401 (k) plans and properly prepare for their retirement. +While there is no doubt that it is increasingly difficult for workers +to plan for a secure retirement, there is much that can be done to make +this security more attainable. I look forward to hearing our witness' +ideas on this issue. + ______ + + [The prepared statement of Mr. Hare follows:] + +Prepared Statement of Hon. Phil Hare, a Representative in Congress From + the State of Illinois + + Since the beginning of the 110th Congress, the Education and Labor +Committee has been investigating what has been termed the ``middle +class squeeze,'' referring to the challenges the majority of Americans +face in acquiring financial stability, affording high healthcare costs, +saving for college and building retirement security, despite having +jobs with strong wages. I am happy to see today we are reviewing the +issue of retirement and the roadblocks involved in pension and +retirement plans that make it difficult for the middle class to build +retirement security. + There is no doubt that we all support employer-sponsored retirement +plans and would like to help facilitate the expansion of those plans by +providing the support and assistance employers need. However, I will +not support efforts that do this on the backs of hard-working +employees. The discussion about hidden fees in 401(k) plans, which the +majority of American workers have, is extremely upsetting to me. Full +disclosure of these fees is critical so that employees have full +knowledge about their investments and the ability to compare plans to +choose the best one for them. +Questions for the Panel + Mr. Chambers: Would requiring the disclosure of these fees +discourage employers from offering retirement plans because of +increased administrative costs? What do your clients need from the +federal government in order to provide reasonable retirement options +for their employees? + Ms. Bovbjerg: We as Members of Congress are privileged in +that we have the best retirement plan in the world--the Thrift Savings +Plan (TSP). The government will match employee contributions to this +plan up to 5%. We also have the choice among many investment options. +What can we do as legislators either through better disclosure +reporting or financial offsets to expand TSP-type plans to all sectors +of the American workforce? + Mr. Hutcheson: How did this ``culture'' come to be that +has allowed unscrupulous extractions from the bank accounts of +hardworking Americans? How do we reestablish the integrity of our +retirement structure? Can disclosure or elimination of hidden fees do +it alone? And, what options do employees have once they know about the +hidden fees they are paying? + ______ + + Chairman Miller. Well, thank you very much. I think your +testimony and your comments and your responses to the members +of the committee have been very helpful for this initial +hearing. And we would hope that you would agree with Mr. +McKeon, that you would continue to serve as a source of +information to us, as we continue this discussion. + Thank you. The committee will stand adjourned. Thank you. + [Whereupon, at 12:55 p.m., the committee was adjourned.] + + + +