diff --git "a/data/CHRG-112/CHRG-112hhrg64552.txt" "b/data/CHRG-112/CHRG-112hhrg64552.txt" new file mode 100644--- /dev/null +++ "b/data/CHRG-112/CHRG-112hhrg64552.txt" @@ -0,0 +1,2495 @@ + +
+[House Hearing, 112 Congress] +[From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] + + + + + CAN MONETARY POLICY REALLY CREATE JOBS? +======================================================================= + + HEARING + + BEFORE THE + + SUBCOMMITTEE ON + + DOMESTIC MONETARY POLICY + + AND TECHNOLOGY + + OF THE + + COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES + + U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES + + ONE HUNDRED TWELFTH CONGRESS + + FIRST SESSION + + __________ + + FEBRUARY 9, 2011 + + __________ + + Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services + + Serial No. 112-3 + + + +[GRAPHIC NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] + + + + U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE +64-552 PDF WASHINGTON: 2011 +____________________________________________________________________________ +For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, +http://bookstore.gpo.gov. For more information, contact the GPO Customer Contact Center, U.S. Government Printing Office. Phone 202-512-1800, or 866-512-1800 (toll-free). E-mail, [email protected]. + + + HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES + + SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama, Chairman + +JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Vice BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts, + Chairman Ranking Member +PETER T. KING, New York MAXINE WATERS, California +EDWARD R. ROYCE, California CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York +FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois +RON PAUL, Texas NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York +DONALD A. MANZULLO, Illinois MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina +WALTER B. JONES, North Carolina GARY L. ACKERMAN, New York +JUDY BIGGERT, Illinois BRAD SHERMAN, California +GARY G. MILLER, California GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York +SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West Virginia MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts +SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas +RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri +PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York +JOHN CAMPBELL, California JOE BACA, California +MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts +KENNY MARCHANT, Texas BRAD MILLER, North Carolina +THADDEUS G. McCOTTER, Michigan DAVID SCOTT, Georgia +KEVIN McCARTHY, California AL GREEN, Texas +STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri +BILL POSEY, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin +MICHAEL G. FITZPATRICK, KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota + Pennsylvania ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado +LYNN A. WESTMORELAND, Georgia JOE DONNELLY, Indiana +BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri ANDRE CARSON, Indiana +BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut +SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin GARY C. PETERS, Michigan +NAN A. S. HAYWORTH, New York JOHN C. CARNEY, Jr., Delaware +JAMES B. RENACCI, Ohio +ROBERT HURT, Virginia +ROBERT J. DOLD, Illinois +DAVID SCHWEIKERT, Arizona +MICHAEL G. GRIMM, New York +FRANCISCO R. CANSECO, Texas +STEVE STIVERS, Ohio + + Larry C. Lavender, Chief of Staff + Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology + + RON PAUL, Texas, Chairman + +WALTER B. JONES, North Carolina, WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri, Ranking + Vice Chairman Member +FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York +PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York +BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri AL GREEN, Texas +BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri +NAN A. S. HAYWORTH, New York GARY C. PETERS, Michigan +DAVID SCHWEIKERT, Arizona + C O N T E N T S + + ---------- + Page +Hearing held on: + February 9, 2011............................................. 1 +Appendix: + February 9, 2011............................................. 43 + + WITNESSES + Wednesday, February 9, 2011 + +Bivens, Josh, Ph.D., Macroeconomist, Economic Policy Institute, + Washington, D.C................................................ 13 +DiLorenzo, Thomas J., Professor of Economics, Sellinger School of + Business, Loyola University, Baltimore, Maryland............... 9 +Vedder, Richard K., Distinguished Professor of Economics, Ohio + University..................................................... 11 + + APPENDIX + +Prepared statements: + Paul, Hon. Ron............................................... 44 + Bachus, Hon. Spencer......................................... 47 + Huizenga, Hon. Bill.......................................... 49 + Bivens, Josh................................................. 51 + DiLorenzo, Thomas J.......................................... 72 + Vedder, Richard K............................................ 77 + + + CAN MONETARY POLICY REALLY CREATE JOBS? + + ---------- + + + Wednesday, February 9, 2011 + + U.S. House of Representatives, + Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary + Policy and Technology, + Committee on Financial Services, + Washington, D.C. + The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:04 a.m., in +room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Ron Paul +[chairman of the subcommittee] presiding. + Members present: Representatives Paul, Lucas, Luetkemeyer, +Huizenga, Hayworth, Schweikert; Clay, Maloney, and Green. + Ex officio present: Representative Frank. + Also present: Representative Renacci. + Chairman Paul. This hearing will come to order. + I want to welcome everybody today, our guests as well as +our Members. + And I think we will go ahead and introduce our Members now, +and those who aren't here, we can do it later on. + Before I introduce our side, the members on this side, I do +want to ask unanimous consent for a statement to be inserted +into the record from Spencer Bachus. He is not here today. He +would have liked to have attended, but he had to attend a +funeral. + Also, I would like to just mention those individuals who +are here. + First, we have Congressman Lucas from Oklahoma. He is an +old hand at this. And I think sitting next to him is Blaine +Luetkemeyer from Missouri. + Welcome. + And I think we have a guest who is not a member of the +subcommittee, and that is Jim Renacci from Ohio. + As others come in, we can recognize them. + I will defer at the moment here to the ranking member to +introduce his Members who are here. + Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + First, let me congratulate you on your election as chairman +of the subcommittee. And I look forward to working with you in +the 112th Congress. + Joining us today is the overall ranking member of the +Financial Services Committee, the gentleman from Massachusetts, +Mr. Barney Frank. And I want to thank him for being here today. + Also with us is a fellow Texan of yours, Mr. Al Green, who +represents the City of Houston. And thank you for being here. + And, of course, I am William Lacy Clay of Missouri. + Chairman Paul. Thank you very much. + I do want to also welcome the Congressman and ranking +member from Massachusetts. We have worked in the past on many +of these issues, to the surprise of some people at times. But I +am glad he is attending today. + Mr. Frank. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would add, to the +surprise and occasional dismay of other people. + Chairman Paul. But the reason I said kind words is I expect +him to behave today. That is all. + I would like to ask unanimous consent that all the +statements of any member can be admitted into the record. If +there is no objection, they will be admitted. + Oh, and I do need to ask unanimous consent for Jim Renacci +to sit with us today. + No objection is heard. + I would like to go ahead and start with an opening +statement, and then I will defer to the other Members who care +to make statements, as well. + Today, we are talking mainly about unemployment. And, to +me, this is a very significant issue that we all care about. I +have not yet met anybody in the Congress or anywhere who thinks +we shouldn't do something about it, so it is unanimous. +Unemployment is too high, and the goal is to keep unemployment +low and employment high. And this would make everybody happy. + But the disagreement seems to come from trying to +understand how we got unemployment and what we should do about +it. And I have argued that if you don't know exactly why we +have unemployment, it is very hard to come up with a solution. + That is the purpose of these hearings, at least initially, +to try to understand the ramifications and especially the +connection of unemployment to monetary policy. Because people +are thinking more about the Federal Reserve policy today than +ever before. And everybody does have opinions. Some people +think there is too much easy money and credit and interest +rates are too low, and others complain on the other side and +say that we need more of it, we need more expansion of credit +and we need more spending. + So that is where the disagreements are. But I think there +should be a lot of goodwill here in the goal of finding out +just what causes our problems and what we can agree on and what +we can do about it. + Between 2001 and 2010, we had a population growth of 26 +million people. Yet, at the end of that decade, we had 2.3 +million less people employed. So these numbers aren't very +encouraging. It is terrible that there are 2.3 million people +not employed, but I think it might even underestimate the +problem since we had such a big population growth. + Just in the last 3 years, or between 2007 and 2010, we had +7 million jobs lost. I do know that we have had some increase +in jobs in the last year, but we are still way behind the +curve. + But even with the job increase, we here in Washington, the +combination of the Fed and what the Congress has done, we +probably have pumped in $4 trillion. And if you look at the new +jobs we have created, I would say they are very, very expensive +jobs. I imagine we could have given everybody $60,000 or +$70,000, maybe $100,000--I haven't done the calculation--just +given them the money and they would have been better off. And +that, of course, would have satisfied the people who say we +have to stimulate spending; the money would be there. But, +instead, the money went in different places, and the +unemployment rates haven't dropped. + Another problem I see when we deal with the unemployment is +sometimes we get confused on how we measure it. The lead figure +from the Bureau of Labor Statistics comes up every month, and +they tell us that unemployment is 9 percent. And, oh, it is +down from 9.5 down to 9; there is a great recovery going on. +But the people don't feel that way. The unemployment rate is +still very high. + And if you look to some of the private sources of measuring +unemployment, you find out that unemployment may well be much +higher. Even the government statistics reveal that if you count +all the people who are just partially employed or working part- +time on weekends, that number can jump to 16 or 17 percent. But +then if you include all those individuals who have given up +looking for work, there are some who report that the +unemployment rate could be 22 or 23 percent, reaching almost +the height of the Depression. + So I would encourage all of us to think more seriously +about how we measure unemployment, and if this is a real +problem, that we ought to do something about defining how to +measure unemployment. + I think in this discussion today, certainly we will be +thinking about the results, the inefficiency of the Federal +Reserve, because they have had a mandate, and the Congress gave +them a mandate, and the mandate is that we should have stable +prices and high employment. I can produce some statistics, and +maybe later on will, to show that prices really aren't all that +stable. And, certainly, unemployment reflects a failure. If +that is their job, they didn't do a very good job. They haven't +been very efficient in producing jobs. + So these are the things we want to talk about and try to +resolve and then see what needs to be done. Because, like I +said, who wants high unemployment? Nobody wants high +unemployment. We want to get people employed. I work from the +assumption that there is a direct connection between monetary +policy and the business cycle, and, therefore, we should pay +more attention to it. + Now I would like to yield to the ranking member, Mr. Clay. + Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + We were all privileged to witness President Obama's +stirring State of the Union Address. And part of his uplifting +message was an appeal for all of us to find common ground in +order to move our Nation forward. That applies here at home and +around the world, as well. + But I am amazed that some of my colleagues in the Majority +may have taken that concept a little bit too far. I never +thought that I would see the day when allegedly conservative +members of the Republican Party would side with the People's +Republic of China over the best advice of the Chairman of the +Federal Reserve. The Republican assertion that the Fed's +actions to infuse the money supply in order to hold down +interest rates and lower unemployment will somehow harm our +currency is absolutely wrong. + The congressional mandate for the Federal Reserve is really +a two-sided coin. The Fed has a mission to both maintain stable +prices and to foster conditions that promote job growth. If we +expect this recovery to continue, we need to support both sides +of that equation. + As Chairman Bernanke has testified previously, this +recession was unlike other post-war economic downturns. And I +am thankful that the President, along with our congressional +leadership and in coordination with the Federal Reserve, acted +courageously to prevent a second Great Depression and to +preserve the American middle class. + Over the last 19 months, with the help of the Federal +Reserve's wise monetary policy, corporate profits have soared, +financial markets have stabilized and regained much of the +value equities that was lost, and the private sector has +created more than 1 million new jobs. And we still have a long +way to go, but that is more new job creation than during the +entire two terms of the Bush Administration. + While we strive to restore our economic security, fear of +future inflation is not today's most important problem. In +fact, the core inflation rate is still near 1 percent. The real +danger is if we impede the money supply; then deflation is next +in the economic chain. + We see real growth and recovery in almost every sector of +the economy, in part because of the Fed's actions. +Manufacturing is up, orders for durable goods are up, and car +sales are better than expected, although too few, which is why +we cannot let up now. There is no doubt that the Fed's prudent +actions to carefully expand the money supply were appropriate, +and they are helping put Americans back to work. + I am not concerned about what the Chinese, the Brazilians, +or the Europeans think about our monetary policy, especially +when some of those who are complaining the loudest are guilty +of manipulating their own currency to hamper American exports, +which cost jobs here at home. The current monetary policy +supports job creation here in America. Here in Congress, we +have no higher priority. + I thank you, and I yield back the balance of my time. + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + I would like now to yield to Congressman Luetkemeyer for +his opening statement. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you for +holding the hearing. And I am pleased to serve on the +subcommittee and glad to see that we are focusing on the most +important issues facing our constituents: jobs. + Since 1977, the Federal Reserve has been charged with two +principal missions: controlling inflation; and maximizing +employment. Despite recent attempts by the Fed, unemployment +continues to hover at 9 percent for the 8th consecutive month, +and the economy is still struggling, leaving one to wonder if +the Fed is capable of affecting either or have they mismanaged +the situation. + Then there is the question of whether the Fed should remain +to have a dual mandate. And that one has been continually +debated since 1977. It is unclear whether this dual mandate +does much of anything to promote job growth. + Take, for example, Chairman Bernanke's quantitative easing +plan. When first presented with the Fed's plan, Americans were +told that this would be the vehicle to keep interest rates low +in order to promote job growth and investment. By injecting +hundreds of billions into the American financial system, the +Fed sought to promote affordable business investment and +economic recovery. This was a bold step, one that could +ultimately our recovery by contributing to inflation. It is my +hope that the $600 billion QE2 will promote lending and +stimulate growth. + At the same time, I am concerned that the Fed and other +Federal regulators seem to be ignoring a key problem: excessive +regulation along the lines of a lack of forbearance among +examiners. As a former bank examiner, I believe the lack of +responsible forbearance practiced by our regulators is +imprudent. Time after time, I have heard from Missouri bankers +who are troubled by increasing pressure from examiners to +shrink their portfolios, even when the loans are performing. + I fully support prudent financial regulatory oversight, but +it is not in our best interest to promote economic policy that +denies credit for viable projects and forces performing +borrowers into insolvency. + Sound monetary policy will play a role in restoring our +Nation's economic stability. We need to energize the private +sector and get the government out of the way by creating a +regulatory environment that protects the American people while +promoting economic expansion. + With that, Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Thank you. + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + I would now like to yield to the ranking member of the full +committee, Mr. Frank, for an opening statement. + Mr. Frank. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + And I would begin by saying I agree with the comments just +concluded. We have suffered from excessive rigidity on the part +of the regulators. We have, on a bipartisan basis, over the +past few years, the past year in particular, talked about the +problem of mixed messages coming from Washington, of the top +regulators saying they want to encourage lending but of our +being told by bankers that they are encountering a great deal +of excessive rigidity. And we will, I hope, continue to press +for a reasonable approach on the part of the bank examiners. + And we also have been engaged in conversations with the +accounting board so that banks are not forced to take steps +that are artificial and lock in a temporary problem, with a +reduction in lending. + But on the subject of today's hearing, I was, as the +gentleman from Missouri was, surprised to see many of my +Republican colleagues here and former members of Republican +Administrations criticizing the Federal Reserve's quantitative +easing partly because it was unfair to foreign countries. As +the gentleman from Missouri pointed out, we had people +explicitly agreeing with foreign critiques, saying that, among +other things, what was wrong with what the Federal Reserve was +doing was it was damaging the currencies of other countries. +And as he noted, the People's Republic of China, in particular, +was helping organize opposition to the Federal Reserve. + Let's be very clear: Being accused of currency manipulation +by the People's Republic of China is like getting a lecture on +family planning from the Octomom. This is a country which has +engaged in very serious and significant and systematic +manipulation of its currency to our economic disadvantage. + In fact, with regard to what the Federal Reserve has done, +the negative predictions haven't come true. We have not seen +inflation. We have not seen a great set of losses. We now know +more about what the Federal Reserve is doing. And I know the +gentleman from Texas does not think we went far enough in what +we did last year in the bill, but we did make several steps +that improved the transparency of what the Federal Reserve +does. And under the law that we now have in place, no +transaction between the Federal Reserve and any private entity +will remain secret forever. There will be a publication of +every transaction that the Federal Reserve does with any +private entity, although, in some cases, with a time lag to +prevent there from being market distortion. + But to go back to this, yes, it is true that unemployment +is still too high. But when you are dealing with economics, the +question is not simply what the reality is but what the reality +would have been in the absence of actions, what the economists +call the ``counterfactual.'' And I think it is very clear that, +as part of an overall approach, what the Federal Reserve has +done has helped bring unemployment down below what it otherwise +would have been, although not to a satisfactory level. + But it is very clear that, with regard to the charge that +it was going to lead to inflation, whether that was going to be +very costly to the Federal Government, or that the Federal +Reserve would be engaged in activities which it could not +unwind, they have all been disproven by the facts. And we do +have speculation--inflation may be coming later. But there has +not been an inflationary problem. The problem continues to be +the lack of employment to catch up with other aspects of growth +in the economy. + And I believe that Mr. Bernanke has been doing, with the +overwhelming support of the other members of the Federal +Reserve, including--remember, this is not just Mr. Bernanke. +There have been a couple of dissents, but the Open Market +Committee includes other appointees, and it includes Federal +Reserve Bank presidents. They have most recently been unanimous +on this. And I think that the effect has been a good one. + And I hope that we will, as a bipartisan approach, tell the +rest of the world that any suggestion that America should be +constrained in what we do to stimulate jobs in this country +will be unaffected by their concerns that it might have some +impact on their own currencies, particularly those whose +manipulation of their own currencies has been to our +disadvantage. + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + Now, I would like to yield time for an opening statement to +Mr. Lucas from Oklahoma. + Mr. Lucas. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I appreciate the +opportunity to offer an opening statement. + I would simply observe, I think, that we all realize that +the Fed's, in effect, running the printing presses perhaps is +the best policy alternative they have there right now in this +situation. But if you believe that price stability ultimately +is what the economy needs to be rational and make decisions and +grow for the long-term period, then you have to ask the +question: By dramatically increasing the supply of money--yes, +the volatility, the circulation of the currency, of money +through the economy slowed dramatically, so that increased +supply has been offset by the reduced activity has provided +price stability or close to it. + But if the Fed didn't see this mess coming in the +beginning, will they see the inflation side in time also? If +they didn't see this mess coming, will they see the inflation +cycle starting up in time, the recovery in time to turn off the +printing press, to shrink the supply, to offset the increased +speed of circulation before we get into inflation? I am not +sure, based on past history, that their vision in the future is +going to be any better than it was in the past. + That, I think, is the question. Not so much what other +countries think, but will we, by the printing press, cause more +problems in the future than we can overcome? + I appreciate the opportunity to hear our witnesses, Mr. +Chairman. + Chairman Paul. I thank you. + I would like to now yield for an opening statement to Mr. +Green from Texas. + Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thank the ranking +member, as well, and I thank the witnesses for appearing. And, +of course, I thank the ranking member of the full committee, +the Honorable Barney Frank. + Mr. Chairman, I would like to start on a positive note and +say that I concur with you 1,000 percent; we do have to +ascertain what the cause was if we are to truly find a +conclusion as to how to resolve the problem. We may differ on +what the cause is, but I do agree that we have to know what the +cause was. + And I would also concur with you that U6 is a good +indicator of what the unemployment rate really is when you add +all of those who are marginally employed. QE1 and QE2 are +important because they have infused capital into the economy. +But when we look at the cause and we connect these two, we find +that we have to ask ourselves, was the cause a lack of +regulation or was it overregulation? I suspect not, in terms of +over. Was it a case of regulators not really regulating? Was it +the exotic products? If it was the exotic products, why were +the exotic products allowed to exist in the first place? + So there are plenty of questions to ask, and I plan to ask +some of the witnesses today. + But with reference to the inflation, I believe that the +chairman has embarked upon a path that is going to help us have +a softer landing than we would have but for the QE1 and QE2. +Without them, it is counterfactual, but there are economists +that tell us that we would have a landing that may have been a +crash, and it may have been devastating for the economy, much +more so than where we are now. + I thank you for the time. I look forward to hearing from +the witnesses. And I yield back. + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + Now I would like to yield time to Congressman Huizenga from +Michigan for an opening statement. + Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate the +opportunity. In the interest of time, I have submitted my +remarks, as well, and will try to shorten it up. And I +appreciate you holding this subcommittee hearing today. + By trade, I am a small-business owner and involved in both +real estate and construction. And I now represent a district +currently suffering an unemployment rate well above the +national average, in Michigan. And one of the hearing's +topics--and this particular hearing holds special significance +for us back in Michigan. + Earlier this month, the Bureau of Labor Statistics reported +that the national unemployment rate fell from 9.4 percent to 9 +percent. That does not include the hundreds of thousands who +have, frankly, stopped looking. That equates to 14 million +people without a job. While this is a staggering number, in my +home State of Michigan we are far worse off: 11.7 percent. And, +again, that is not including those who have stopped looking. +And in some of the areas in my particular district, along the +lakeshore, it is well over double the national average. + As previously mentioned, I am a small-business owner at +heart and believe such businesses are the backbone of the U.S. +economy and provide more than two-thirds of American jobs. I +understand the universal principles of successful business, and +it is important that we recognize the appropriate role for +government in that process. Simply put, the private sector +creates jobs, not the public sector. And that is ultimately +where that prosperity lies. + It is clear to all small-business owners that responsible +fiscal policy includes reduced government spending and the +implementation of friendly tax and regulatory environments. +They go a long way in creating an atmosphere for success. + As we are having this discussion on QE1 and QE2, ultimately +I believe that they have not proven to be an effective method +in creating jobs. And I appreciate today us examining the +effects that the Federal Reserve open market operations have on +those long- and short-term unemployment rates. And, in +addition, I look forward to carefully inspecting what potential +role the Fed policies played in such artificial asset bubbles +as that of the housing market between 2001 and 2008. + So I look forward to today's, I would guess, robust +conversation on the short-term effects. And I appreciate your +holding this hearing, Mr. Chairman. So thank you very much. I +yield back. + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + Now, I would like to yield time to Congresswoman Hayworth +from New York, a new member to the committee. + Dr. Hayworth. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + My home district is New York's 19th. It is the Hudson +Valley. And we have a large portion of our constituency who +have jobs in the financial services sector. And, frankly, all +of our citizens are quite directly affected by what the Federal +Reserve is doing and has done in the past. So I am honored to +be working on this subcommittee, because examining the role of +monetary policy in the financial crisis and in our response to +it is crucial. + History shows that an independent central bank that is +making monetary decisions free of political influence can +certainly enhance economic growth. It stabilizes the currency. +That is very important. But that is very different from +requiring a central bank to be held accountable for its +decisions and to explain why it is making them. And it is +certainly incumbent upon us to set that policy for monitoring +and holding accountable. + So that is our role here. And we are in service of the far +larger goal, as my colleague from Michigan has said, of getting +Americans back to work throughout the country. So I look +forward to your testimony regarding how monetary policy has +affected unemployment. I am sure it has. + And I yield back the remainder of my time. Thank you, Mr. +Chairman. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + The Congressman from North Carolina, Walter Jones, has +arrived. He is the vice chairman of this committee. + Would you like to make an opening statement? + Mr. Jones. No. + Chairman Paul. We would like to announce and celebrate the +notion that Walter is going to have a birthday tomorrow. So we +want to wish him a happy birthday. + Mr. Jones. Thank you. + Chairman Paul. Okay. If we don't have any more opening +statements, we are going to go to the guests that we have, +those who are going to testify. I want to welcome all three of +the individuals here today. And I will read a brief resume of +each one, and then we will go to the discussion. + First, on the left, we have Professor Thomas DiLorenzo, +professor of economics at the Sellinger School of Business at +Loyola University in Baltimore, Maryland, and a senior fellow +at the Ludwig von Mises Institute in Auburn, Alabama. He +received his Ph.D. in economics from Virginia Polytechnic +Institute and State University at Virginia Tech. + Next, will be Professor Richard Vedder, the Edwin and Ruth +Kennedy Distinguished Professor of Economics at Ohio University +and an adjunct scholar at the American Enterprise Institute. He +received his B.A. in economics from Northwestern University and +his M.A. and Ph.D. in economics from the University of +Illinois. He is the author of, ``Out of Work: Unemployment and +Government in Twentieth-Century America.'' + And finally, we will hear from Dr. Josh Bivens, an +economist at the Economic Policy Institute in Washington, D.C. +He received his B.A. in economics from the University of +Maryland and his Ph.D. in economics from the New School of +Social Research. + Each will be given time for an opening statement, and their +full statements will be put into the record. + So I will first now defer to Dr. DiLorenzo. + + STATEMENT OF THOMAS J. DILORENZO, PROFESSOR OF ECONOMICS, + SELLINGER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, LOYOLA UNIVERSITY, BALTIMORE, + MARYLAND + + Mr. DiLorenzo. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and members of the +committee for giving me this opportunity to appear here. + To answer the basic question that has been posed by this +hearing, can monetary policy really create jobs, as an academic +economist, you are not surprised to hear from me that the +answer is ``yes and no.'' + And the reason why I say ``yes and no'' is that the history +of the Fed has been that it has created boom-and-bust cycles in +the economy ever since it began its existence in 1914. And so, +during the boom period, of course, it does create jobs, but the +jobs that it creates, many of them are unsustainable jobs. I +can recall hearing that Home Depot, when they laid off 7,000 +people in 1 day, these were jobs that people had invested in, +they invested their lives, their careers, and then the rug was +pulled out from under them. That is the sort of thing that +happens with what we call the artificial boom and bust created +by the Fed's monetary policies. + And the key to it is that the monetary expansion that the +Fed creates, it sometimes produces price inflation, but that is +not the only problem. Another part of the problem is that it +artificially lowers interest rates and induces businesses to +engage in especially long-term investments that end up being +unsustainable. + In the latest boom-and-bust cycle, that was mostly in real +estate and everything related to real estate. But it is not +necessarily just real estate. And so, in this latest cycle +then, you had people, mortgage bankers and insurance companies +and everyone related in every way to housing construction +investing years and years of their careers, and then they are +out of work; they have to retool. + The lower interest rates are not necessarily an unmixed +blessing to everyone because they tend to reduce savings, and +savings and investment are the key to productivity growth and +job creation. And so, the downside of the Fed policy of +lowering interest rates lower and lower is that it deters +savings. And savings investment is really the key to having +sustainable economic growth and job creation. + The real damage occurs, then, during the boom cycle of the +business cycle, where capital is misallocated. Too much of it +goes into unsustainable areas, such as real estate in the +latest bout here. And the best part, the good part, if you can +say there is a good part to this boom-and-bust cycle, is now +the bust is where the adjustments have to take place. And we +have to get back to realistic prices, realistic interest rates. + One problem the Fed creates, though, is, with its constant +manipulation of interest rates, it really is an attempt at +price controls. And I think the economics profession is almost +unanimous in opposition against price controls. And interest +rates are prices. And so, when the Fed tries to manipulate +interest rates, it is really engaging in a policy of price +controls. And a lot of people in this room, I am sure, remember +what a disaster that was in the 1970s, with price controls on +oil and gas. + Now, government policies that bail out businesses, which we +have seen, is really a contradiction of an age-old rule of +economics with regard to monetary policy. The rule was, in the +case of a recession like this, it is a good idea for the Fed to +make credit available to sound businesses that have been +responsible and made good decisions, but not make more credit +available to those businesses who have made bad decisions. And +it is better off to let them go bankrupt, out of business, and +have those resources be picked up, reallocated by people who +will make better use of them. But, of course, the Fed has done +exactly the opposite of that in the recent years. + And so, as applied to today's situation, I think a very +strong case could be made that the cause of the boom was the +Greenspan Fed's low-interest policies. So the Fed did create +some jobs with the boom; it is responsible for creating those +jobs. But I think it is also responsible for the high +unemployment that we now suffer to a very large extent because +of the bust that has occurred. + It also has created mismatched unemployment, what +economists used to call mismatched unemployment, which I +referred to a minute ago, in terms of people investing in jobs +and careers that ultimately are not sustainable for a long +period of time. + Historically, the Fed, right from the very beginning, as +soon as it started in 1914, it doubled the money supply by that +date in 1920 and created the Depression of 1920. It was the +worst depression in the first year of the Great Depression. And +a strong case can be made--and I can refer any of the Members +to literature if they would ask me for it, as to where you can +read up on how the boom and bust of the 1920s was caused by the +Fed, as was, I would even argue, the Great Depression was +ignited by the expansionary monetary policy of the Fed, not the +restrictive monetary policy of the Fed, that occurred from 1929 +to 1932. + I see my time is about up. So, in summary, I will say that +the Fed's monetary policies do create temporary but +unsustainable increases in employment, while being the very +engine of recession and depression, even, that creates +unemployment in the long run. And it needs to step back, in my +view, and let the market work and create a lot more stability +by quitting its attempts to manipulate the price of credit, +interest rates. + Thank you very much. + [The prepared statement of Dr. DiLorenzo can be found on +page 72 of the appendix.] + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + I would like to now defer to Professor Vedder for his +statement. + + STATEMENT OF RICHARD K. VEDDER, DISTINGUISHED PROFESSOR OF + ECONOMICS, OHIO UNIVERSITY + + Mr. Vedder. Thank you, Dr. Paul. + The one-word executive summary of my answer to the +hearing's question, can monetary policy really create jobs, the +one-word answer is ``no.'' And I would agree with Dr. +DiLorenzo, no, not in the long run, or no, not on a sustainable +basis. + A little historical context: The first decade of this +century had the lowest rate of economic growth of any decade +since the Great Depression. Employment growth was the lowest in +6 decades. Inflation-adjusted equity prices fell sharply. + In large part, I think this reflects a multitude of faulty +government policies, certainly on the fiscal side. Federal +spending soared, increasingly financed by borrowing. The ratio +of national debt to output is at a historic high for a +relatively peaceful period. And on the monetary side, we had +the worst financial crisis since the Depression, with many +iconic financial institutions closing their doors or only +surviving because of Federal bailouts. And despite all these +huge Federal exertions on both the fiscal and monetary side, we +have had the weakest recovery going on now in the lifetime of +most persons in this room. + Moreover, I think the huge run-up in the ratio of Federal +debt to output will be a significant drag on the economy for +many years and may well lead the Fed to monetize this debt or +part of this debt, unleashing a wave of inflation that can only +undermine our economy. + Turning to the 2008 fiscal crisis, financial crisis, +certainly private irrational exuberance may have occurred to +some extent. The crisis largely resulted from three types of +government policies, failures. + First, as Tom DiLorenzo indicated, the Federal Reserve for +years prior to the crisis pursued an easy money policy, +reducing interest rates below levels justified by human +behavior and market conditions. This led to the artificial boom +in housing prices. + Second, the Feds encouraged imprudent lending practices +through such things as the Community Reinvestment Act, HUD +policies going back to the 1990s designed to promote +homeownership. + Third, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, government-sponsored +corporations, promoted totally inappropriate lending practices +that contributed to the housing bubble and the foreclosure +mess. Congress blocked attempts to rein in these companies, no +doubt, frankly, because of the campaign contributions these +companies made to Members of this body. + I am an economic historian. And both economics and +historical experience demonstrate that Federal intrusions into +economic activity are counterproductive. Some textbooks even +talk about the ``policy ineffectiveness theorem.'' Aggressive +deficit spending and Federal Reserve monetary expansion led to +stagflation in the 1970s. Japan went on a huge binge of +stimulus spending in the 1990s, and economic growth virtually +ground to a halt. The excesses of the European welfare state +and its funding are causing crises all over the European Union, +from Ireland to Greece. The stimulus plans of the Obama +Administration were accompanied by rising, not falling, +unemployment. Bailouts and ``too-big-to-fail'' policies have +created a huge moral hazard problem. The Federal Reserve has +engaged in huge purchases of government long-term bonds and +mortgages to keep interest rates low. But long-term interest +rates are not falling, as concerns about potential inflation +justifiably have risen. + So, by many indicators, this is the weakest post-war +recovery, not because we have tried too little, but because we +have tried too much. The Fed and the government have monetary +and fiscal time bombs that are threatening both the short-term +recovery but, more importantly, long-term financial and +economic stability. + So what do you do? I would point out that our economy +achieved economic supremacy in the world from 1871 to 1914, a +period of the gold standard, near-stable prices, and no central +bank. Consumer prices in 1914 were within 10 percent of what +they were in 1871. We can learn from that experience. + To restore monetary stability, ideally we would ultimately +consider retreating somewhat from the fractional reserve +banking system we have, where even moderate declines in +confidence potentially lead to devastating consequences. But +more immediately, we need to limit monetary growth. And, given +human weaknesses, probably the best way to do this ultimately +is having a gold standard or some variant that removes or +dramatically reduces the discretion of central bankers. + But on the fiscal side, politicians, unfettered by rules, +behave, I would say, like unsupervised alcoholics in liquor +stores. We need some sort of constitutional restraints on +government fiscal actions. Practically, changes of this +magnitude take time, but, in the short run, however, I think +you could start holding the Fed's feet to the fire. Perhaps, +for starters, you should establish price stability as the +single monetary mandate for the Fed. Perhaps you should repeal +the Humphrey-Hawkins Act and privatize or abolish Fannie Mae or +Freddie Mac. + After that, you can rest on Sunday. + [The prepared statement of Dr. Vedder can be found on page +77 of the appendix.] + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + We will move on now to Dr. Josh Bivens for his statement. + + STATEMENT OF JOSH BIVENS, MACROECONOMIST, ECONOMIC POLICY + INSTITUTE, WASHINGTON, D.C. + + Mr. Bivens. Thank you. I would like to thank the committee +and the chairman for inviting me here today. + The subject of this hearing is, can monetary policy really +create jobs? I am going to say the answer is a barely equivocal +``yes,'' and the equivocation just being it can create jobs as +long as the economy is performing below potential. And the +economy is performing below potential today. + The argument--I am going to start with just a little bit of +theory. Of course, theory alone can't end the discussion, so +then I will talk about some evidence on monetary policy's +effects. + So the theory--sometimes the cause of recessions are pretty +hard to reconstruct. Not so in what we are now calling the +``great recession.'' The bursting of the housing bubble led to +home builders waking up, realized they had massively overbuilt, +so residential investment collapsed. The 30 percent fall in +home prices also erased about $7 trillion in wealth from +household balance sheets, so they predictably radically +curtailed their spending. + These initial shocks then cascaded throughout the economy. +Businesses stopped investing because customers aren't coming in +the door. Why would you build a new factory when the one you +have can't even sell what it is producing? + And so, in the jargon--and, for once, the jargon is kind of +important--the economy suffered a shock to aggregate demand. +The clear fact that this recession was the result of a shock to +aggregate demand is key. Americans workers didn't lose their +skills in December 2007. American factories didn't become +obsolete in that month. American managers didn't forget how to +organize production in that month. Nothing changed about the +American economy's ability to supply goods and services. All +that changed was the ability of households and businesses to +purchase them. The erasure of all the wealth from the housing +bubble was a shock to aggregate demand. + So what the Fed tried to do is stabilize economic activity +by providing a countervailing spur to demand with the levers +they have. The primary lever they have is short-term interest +rates. By lowering these short-term rates, or policy rates, the +hope is that interest rates up and down the term and risk +structure fall in sympathy. That makes it cheaper for +businesses to borrow to expand capacity. That makes it cheaper +for households to borrow to buy new houses, and durable goods. +It also provides a one-time boost to asset prices. And so this +decline in policy interest rates is meant to provide a +countervailing, positive spur to the aggregate demand that was +quashed by the bursting of the housing bubble. + And all this happened as the great recession approached. +The Fed started cutting these policy rates in August 2007. They +provided extraordinary support to failing financial +institutions early in 2008. And about halfway through the great +recession, the policy rates they controlled had kind of run out +of ammunition. They were sitting at zero. + They could have just stopped there. As the economy was in a +complete free fall, as the primary parachute they have +available to them obviously wasn't sufficient, they could have +stopped there. They didn't. And it is a good thing they didn't. +They continued to try to find other ways to provide support to +the economy with the quantitative easing programs. + And these interventions worked. If you look at when the Fed +introduced the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, the +day that was introduced, credit spreads on asset-backed +securities started to rapidly fall. That was very good for the +economy. It meant people could actually get credit again. + Researchers from the San Francisco Fed say that the +announcements of both rounds of quantitative easing caused +interest rates to fall up and down the term structure. Some of +the members of the committee may have noticed that 30-year home +mortgages fell to something like 4 percent in the past couple +of months. Some of us in this room may have even refinanced +their mortgages. I actually did. It saved me a lot of money, +and provided a spur to my spending power. That is very good for +the economy. That is one channel that is supposed to work. + Just that channel alone, the ability to refinance, some +researchers at JPMorgan Chase have estimated that, if all the +mortgages guaranteed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had been +able to take advantage of those 4 percent rates we saw a couple +of months ago and refinance, that would be a permanent $50 +billion spur to spending potential in the economy. That is just +one channel through which monetary policy can help people start +spending again, and businesses. + And if you look back, you look at studies of what ended the +Great Depression, Christina Romer, eminent economic historian, +the former CEA chair for the Obama Administration, she says +that monetary easing was a key part of what ended the Great +Depression. I would say she is actually criticized in this view +by, say, Milton Friedman, probably the most famous conservative +economist, only because he thinks the Fed should have done much +more, loosened much more to fight the Great Depression. + If you look at Adam Posen, probably the closest observer of +what happened in Japan in the 1990s, he points to the fact that +Japan actually had a pretty good recovery from 2002 to 2008 +when they finally started engaging in the unconventional +monetary easing that the Fed has done during the great +recession. It was the first time Japan had seen serious growth +in decades. + The Japanese case is also instructive because they had a +20-year period where they kept the short-term interest rates +that they controlled, the Bank of Japan, near zero. They +engaged in lots of quantitative easing. The cumulative +inflation rate over those 2 decades was less than 5 percent. +The United States has seen inflation of over 5 percent, or +close to 5 percent, in a single year in the 2000s. So this idea +that monetary easing always leads to inflation, no matter what, +is just not supported by the facts. + And so, my time is up, and I just want to say one thing. I +would say that the Fed has been by far the policymaking +institution most aggressive in its response to the job crisis +caused by the great recession. It acted first, it acted most +aggressively, and it continues to display a real sense of +urgency about the need to support the economy and create jobs. + Thank you for your attention. + [The prepared statement of Dr. Bivens can be found on page +51 of the appendix.] + Chairman Paul. I thank the gentleman. + We will now go into our question session. Each Member gets +5 minutes to ask questions. + And just to let you know that if the discussion is still +going on, we will have a second or even a third round of +questions if you are interested in the subject and you want to +hang around. + First, I will start off with asking Dr. Bivens a question, +because you have talked a little bit about interest rates and +how valuable it has been to the economy for the Fed to lower +interest rates. But isn't it true that there comes a point +where they can't accomplish that, where the effort to lower +interest rates doesn't actually lower interest rates? + And we may be even entering that period right now. There is +a lot of monetary inflation right now with QE2, and there are +signs that bonds aren't doing as well and they may be shifting. + What happens to those who agree with your policy? What do +they do if the more they inflate, the higher the interest rate +goes? And, in a way, we had that in the 1970s, as well. Then +what do you do? What is the policy that is necessary to +counteract that when interest rates are going up when you don't +want them to go up? + Mr. Bivens. A couple of things--one, you mentioned the +experience of the 1970s. To me, the experience of the 1970s, +why interest rates were high was because inflation rates were +high. And so, my best guess over the next couple of years--and +it is a guess based on a firm historical relationship between +how much slack is in the economy and inflation rates--we do not +have to worry about spiking inflation in the economy any time +in the next couple of years. + So your scenario where the Fed continues to ease, maybe +undertakes even another round of quantitative easing and +somehow interest rates in the long term start rising, I would +say they would need to reassess the policy then. But my read of +the evidence so far is that, with each announcement of the +rounds of quantitative easing, you have seen a robust fall in +interest rates across the risk and term structure, which was +exactly the target. And it has filtered through to more +spending in the economy. + Chairman Paul. I thank you. + And I would like to get a comment from Dr. Vedder or Dr. +DiLorenzo on that subject. + Mr. Vedder. Let's first talk about--the QE2 was announced +on November 3rd. It is now February 9th. What has happened to +the interest rates on 10-year or 30-year Federal Government +securities in that interim? My read of the evidence--and I just +look at the interest rate yesterday versus November 3rd--is +that the interest rate on 30-year government bonds has risen +somewhere between 65 and 70 basis points. The interest rates on +10-year notes has gone up more than 100 basis points. This has +not moved down. It is not even staying still. It is going up. + Now, in that period, we are buying, what, $50 billion of +bonds a month? We bought several hundred billion--the Fed now +owns a trillion dollars' worth of long-term securities, I +believe, or close to it, the better part of that. + To me, that is just the evidence. And it suggests that your +concern, Dr. Paul, is correct, that the increased inflationary +expectations have overwhelmed the effects, the immediate +effects the Fed has when it pushes up bond prices when it buys +securities. So I think your concern is valid. + Mr. DiLorenzo. Yes, I agree, that is what we are seeing, is +inflationary expectations driving up those interest rates. And +it might not be hyperinflation, but we are beginning to see it. +And you have seen some of the inflation around the world, too. +A lot of the U.S. dollars that are in circulation end up +overseas. And I think there is probably a connection between +the high food prices that you are seeing in different places +around the world with this inflation. + But that is not the only problem that can be created by +monetary expansion. It is the misallocation of resources. The +Fed is creating a different kind of boom with its quantitative +easing. And no one can predict what will happen, but in the +next couple of years we could see another bubble. And I think +it is likely to be much bigger than the housing bubble was. And +then we will really be in trouble. + Chairman Paul. I would like to ask Dr. Bivens first about +his statement on page 7. He says, in short, the Fed saw the +economic downturn coming before any other major macroeconomic +policymaker body. And there have been a lot of others. What do +you do with the free-market Austrian economists? And there were +more than a few. How do you dismiss them so easily? Because +they did predict it correctly. + Mr. Bivens. Yes, I would absolutely not say the Fed was the +first to see it coming of any economist. I have colleagues who +warned in 2002 that home prices were getting too high. I meant +to say they were the first major macroeconomic policymaking +institution. They acted first. + There are three big arms of macroeconomic stabilization: +there is fiscal policy, Congress; there is monetary policy, the +Fed; and there is exchange rate policy controlled by the +Treasury. And of those three institutions, the first one to +start providing lots of easing to the U.S. economy was the Fed. + Chairman Paul. Okay. My time is about up, but I just want +to go on to the next speaker by quoting Mr. Bernanke, and this +was in the fourth quarter of 2007: ``We may see somewhat better +economic conditions during the second half of 2008. This +baseline forecast is consistent with our recently released +projections, which also see growth picking up.'' + He had no idea that it was coming. He was so reassuring, +and he misled so many people. And I just think there is a lot-- +and if I had more time, I would get other comments, but maybe +later on. But it just seems like the Fed was way behind on this +whole issue. I would hate to think they were the first ones to +warn us. I think they were the last ones to even recognize what +was going on. + Okay. And I will now yield to the ranking member, Mr. Clay. + Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, again, let me +commend you for calling this hearing. The causes of +unemployment and how government and the private sector can +respond to and mitigate this crisis are extremely important. +And I thank you for your leadership on this issue right at the +start of this Congress. + Dr. DiLorenzo, you belong to the Austrian school. And we +don't have time for a debate on various economic theories. +However, the Austrian school is different from mainstream +theories in its lack of a scientific method and rejection of +empirical data. You don't use the scientific method and instead +employ deductive reasoning. You apply preconceived +generalizations to your work. You are kind of asking us to take +your word for it. + Without data, without providing verifiable results, it is +difficult for others to evaluate the merits of your work, and +we must rely on your body of work itself. + Doctor, you are here today representing yourself as an +economist. However, it has been difficult for my staff to +locate any recent work of yours as an economist. It seems that +for the past 15 years or so you have published books, written +many articles, and given lectures as an historian. + The lines among the social sciences can sometimes get +blurry, and I am not going to quibble about academic +distinctions. But if your work was on labor history, historical +patterns of unemployment, even the history of the Federal +Reserve on monetary policy, I can understand you being here +today. But I am a little confused. It seems to me that the bulk +of your work has been in revisionist history about our 16th +President, Abraham Lincoln, and the Civil War. + Also--and this is where my confusion deepens to concern-- +you work for a Southern nationalist organization that espouses +very radical notions about American history and the Federal +Government. This organization, The League of the South, has +been identified as a hate group by the Southern Poverty Law +Center. + Now, the Law Center is an organization that I deeply +respect, and so naturally this concerns me. The League of the +South is a neoconfederate group that advocates for a second +Southern secession and a society dominated by European +Americans. It officially classifies the U.S. Government as an +organized criminal enterprise. + Dr. DiLorenzo, you are listed on their Web site as teaching +for their League of the South Institute. A short list of your +many articles includes: ``More Lies About the Civil War''; +``The First Dictator-President'', referring to Abraham Lincoln; +``In Defense of Sedition''; ``Libelist Leftist Lynch Mobs,'' +insensitively using a loaded term to refer to academic +criticism of a White professor; ``Abe the Mass Murderer''; +``Hurrah for `Sweatshops'''--I guess you could sort of claim +that the title at least is somewhat connected or something to +do with economics; and ``Hitler Was a Lincolnite.'' + After reviewing your work and the so-called methods you +employ, I still do not understand your being invited to testify +today on the unemployment crisis, but I do know that I have no +questions for you. + Let me go to Dr. Bivens. + And there are some factual errors in the testimony +presented here today that I believe need to be corrected. +First, even though it was suggested that it was the excessive +expansionary monetary policy of the Fed that caused yet another +boom-and-bust cycle that spawned the Great Depression, the +facts do not bear this out. + And, according to congressional research, between 1925 and +December of 1928, the money supply increased at a very modest +rate of 3.4 percent. Even if we look at a larger timeframe from +July of 1921 to July of 1929, it grew at a rate of 4.8 percent +per year. There is nothing particularly rapid about these +rates, much less anything approaching excessive expansion. + Dr. Bivens, can you confirm this for us? + Mr. Bivens. The exact numbers, no. But they definitely +comport with my sense of that period, which is there was no +excessive monetary expansion before the Great Depression. And +even again, Milton Friedman, conservative economist, if he has +a criticism of the Fed during the Great Depression, it is that +they did not ease quickly enough, they did not provide enough +monetary support to the economy. So they comport with my sense +of what happened during that period. + Mr. Clay. Thank you for responding. + Mr. Chairman, I yield back. + Chairman Paul. I now yield to Congressman Jones from North +Carolina. + Mr. Jones. Mr. Chairman, thank you very much, and thank you +for holding this hearing. + I want to thank the panelists. + And, Mr. Chairman, about a week ago, I decided that the +frustration of the American people in the 3rd District of North +Carolina, which I represent, was so great and their +disappointment in the United States Congress and things we have +done--talking about both parties--that I would take it upon +myself to say, if you will help me with questions for the +panelists for this whole year--I am delighted to be on this +subcommittee, by the way--that I will use some of your +questions when my time comes. + So, Mr. Chairman, in a week's time, we got over a thousand +e-mails from my district. I am going to read two; then I want +to get to a point: + ``Our Congress Members, for the most part, must be the most +financially illiterate group of men and women on the planet. +Why would they need a study group on domestic monetary policy +and technology to figure out you don't print more money to +create jobs that are backed by virtual money, or funny money? I +believe we need to fire all these people and get a couple of +housewives who have been managing their family budget over the +years without credit cards, lines of credit, and other creative +ways to rob Peter to pay Paul.'' + This is a great example of how frustrated the American +people are. That is why I do think this hearing today is +important. + Let me read the next one; then I want to get to the +question: + ``As an owner of small businesses and a family borrower, I +have not understood how the Federal Reserve can keep its +interest rates at almost zero and then make lendable funds more +available to the banks, while at the same time the banks have +increased interest rates, decreased lines of credit, and +restricted availability of loans to high-rated creditors like +my businesses and other households. I can only see that the +banks have improved their financial position on the backs of +small businesses and families.'' + That basically is going to be my question. I am very +frustrated; I am sure my colleagues in both parties are, as +well. What you hear back home is this issue of how the banks +have been empowered with the Federal Reserve and the other +agencies so that they are able to swell their financial state +and, at the same time, they are saying to those of us who are +creditors, we are going to raise your interest rates on your +credit cards, we are going to deny you loans because we have a +certain criteria now. + And this is why this country is in deep trouble, and it is +going to continue in deep trouble. And that is why I think it +is important that we hold these hearings about monetary policy, +because the average American is out there strangling to death +because of things that we do and don't do here in Washington. + How would you answer the question to that constituent who +wrote me that question? Anyone who would like to answer. + Mr. Vedder. I think your constituent ought to be made a +member of the Council of Economic Advisors or something of--it +wouldn't be any worse than it is now, maybe a little bit +better. + Why are interest rates for the ordinary--why are people not +borrowing a lot of money now? Is it because--the reason, of +course, is--why are businesses sitting on $2 trillion in cash, +roughly, right now? They are sitting on $2 trillion. You can +have interest--interest rates don't matter. I don't say they +don't matter. They are not the key thing. + They are scared. People are scared. They are scared of a $4 +trillion increase in the Federal debt over the last 3 years. +The housewife may not be sure why that is bad, but she knows +that is basically not a good thing to do. She knows that +printing money and dropping it out of airplanes, or the +equivalent, which is what the Fed does, will not create jobs, +will not create wealth. It might temporarily lead to some +behavioral modifications that leave the appearance of some +stimulus in the short run, but not in the long run. + I happen to like Abraham Lincoln, by the way, and I went to +the Lincoln Memorial today to read the Gettysburg Address. And +I noticed that they have torn up--that they have drained the +reflecting pool. And there is a sign in front of it that says, +this is part of the stimulus--whatever, the reinvestment--I +don't remember the name of that thing--reinvestment act. And +they also had a sign next to it that said, we are going to fill +it back up again. We can drain the reflecting pool and fill it +back up again and probably put a few people to work for a day +or 2, but that doesn't create jobs. + People are scared. And banks have partly raised interest +rates, to get more specific, on some types of credit because +they feel they have to because of the Dodd-Frank bill. Another +thing, when they see light at the end of the tunnel, you add on +more tunnel. Not you, personally, Congressman, but your +colleagues add more tunnel. And we have added more tunnel. + So we have the Dodd-Frank bill that has all kinds of new +restrictions on banks and financial institutions. They have to +make up the money somewhere. They are not going to just simply +say, oh, we are going to let our profits fall to zero, and we +are going to become a charitable institution, a not-for-profit. +That is not the way banks operate. So they have raised a lot of +fees and so forth. So that has added to the frustration. + Mr. Jones. Would you like-- + Mr. Bivens. Yes, could I have a very quick response to +that, as well? + I will say one thing. If you look at the survey of small +businesses, the National Federation of Independent Business +recently over the past year, you ask them, what is the number- +one problem facing you, overwhelming highest response in +history: sales; there are no customers. + And so then the question is, can monetary policy actually +create some customers for those businesses? And it absolutely +can. When you saw the ability to refinance mortgages at 4 +percent, that freed up a lot of money for households. When you +lower interests up and down the term and risk structure, you +make it much cheaper for businesses who are on that razor's +edge--``Should I borrow a little money to expand? It is +uncertain out there''--but you make it much easier for them to +do that. + And the idea that there are inflationary expectations +driving up long-term rates, there just are not. The clearest +indicator of inflationary expectations that economists use is +the tip spread, the spread between inflation index treasuries +and nominals. That was at historically low levels a couple of +months ago. Now it is still below 2 percent lower than it was +at any point during the 2000s. There is just no sign that +inflationary expectations are out of line and that is what is +driving anything like long-term rates rising. + And then just one last thing. I am no defender of the +banks, but, actually, if you are worried the banks are having +too easy of a time by borrowing cheap, short term from the Fed, +and then raising long rates on what they are lending to their +customers, quantitative easing actually squashes that spread. +It actually makes it less hospitable for banks to do that. So +if you don't like the banks, kind of, riding the easy term +structure created by what the Fed is doing to short-term rates, +you should like the quantitative easing program. + Mr. Jones. Thank you. + Mr. DiLorenzo. Is there time for one more comment on that? + Chairman Paul. Go ahead. + Mr. DiLorenzo. I would add, since I have written three +books that include a history of banking, so contrary to what +Mr. Clay had to say about me, what we have been experiencing is +what economists call ``regime uncertainty.'' With all the +uncertainty of the Fed changing policy month by month--the +threat of huge taxes for socialized medicine, the re-regulation +of banking with the Dodd-Frank bill--businesses sit back and +wait because there is so much great uncertainty about the +future with all of these regulatory changes and tax changes. + And that is one of the things that is keeping them from +lending to businesses. The businesses are putting a lot of +their business plans on hold. And the economist Robert Higgs is +best known for research on this whole area of regime +uncertainty, and I think that is an important thing to factor +in there. + Chairman Paul. I now yield 5 minutes to the Congressman +from Texas, Mr. Green. + Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + I thank the witnesses, as well, again. + What we have, apparently, is this philosophical debate +about how jobs are created. Do millionaires create jobs, or do +millionaires simply respond to demand and, as a result, they +facilitate the creation of jobs because there is demand? + Smart money doesn't create jobs just because it exists. +Smart money creates jobs when there is a demand to be met. Is +that, in essence, what you are trying to say or have been +saying, Dr. Bivens? + Mr. Bivens. Yes, I think that is a fair summary. + Mr. Green. And is it true, sir, that jobs and employment, +that these factors are considered lagging economic indicators, +employment? + Mr. Bivens. That is right. I think that is fair to say, as +well. The last couple of recessions, you have seen GDP go up. + Mr. Green. Right. And while other things will come back at +a relatively different pace--let's say it this way: Jobs will +be among the last things that will return, especially when you +have a sharp downturn in the economy. And it is also fair to +say that, because of some of the structural changes in the +economy, there are some jobs that won't return. Is this a fair +statement? + Mr. Bivens. I think we will have a different-looking +economy coming out of this than we did. We are going to have +fewer construction jobs when we eventually get out of this and +get out of the jobs hole. Hopefully we have some more +manufacturing jobs. So, yes, I think there is something to +that. + Mr. Green. Also, changes in technology. A few years ago, we +had technology that was greatly different. Something as simple +as developing film, the technology has changed. So you won't +have those jobs. Record companies won't have jobs. The +structure of the economy is changing as well. + So I would like for you, if you would, to just do this for +me. Take a moment and explain, if you would, how the lagging +indicator of jobs returning, employment, how that will manifest +itself as we go forward. Is that something that will happen +immediately, or will we see signs of it? + And, also, does it rise and fall based upon people who are +out of the employment market coming back into the market? Does +that then cause the job numbers to go up again? And then as +more people are employed, it comes down again? Please talk +about it. + Mr. Bivens. Yes, you raise a lot of interesting points. + First, I will say that the observation that jobs are a +lagging indicator should absolutely not be taken as +``everything is fine, and the jobs will come back,'' even at +the current pace of economic growth. That is not the case. If +you want jobs to come back really quickly, you need to boost +economic growth that much quicker. And so I would say monetary +ease. + But, yes, then the other issue is, you are right. If you +look at the number of jobs lost between 2007 and today, it is +roughly 7 million. But we should have created well over 3 +million in that time period just to keep pace with population +growth. Those people who didn't join the labor force over the +past 3 years will start joining it if jobs start becoming +available again. And so that means the unemployment rate is +going to be very, very stubborn in coming down over the next +couple of years, even if we get some good output growth, some +good employment growth. + But that said, if you look at the agonizingly slow +recovery, the 2001 recession, or the very slow recovery of +today compared to the quick recovery of the early 1980s; the +thing that distinguishes them is that output grew much faster +in the 1980s. And part of what explains that output growth, as +I say in my written testimony, is the Fed had a lot of room to +provide a lot of monetary support to the economy, and they did. +They cut interest rates by 10 percent. That sparked both output +and jobs growth. + So I think you are right. I think, even as jobs come back, +the unemployment rate is going to be very, very stubborn +because of all those jobs that were not created. But we really +should say we cannot be satisfied with this pace of economic +growth. + Mr. Green. Thank you. + Let me quickly respond to something that was said about the +CRA, and Fannie and Freddie to a certain extent. We do have to +make a distinction between causes and contributing factors. The +CRA did not create 3/27s, 2/28s, teaser rates that coincided +with prepayment penalties, no-doc loans. All of these exotic +products were not created by the CRA. It may have been a +contributing factor, Fannie may have been a contributing +factor, as well as Freddie. But we shouldn't label contributing +factors as causes. + These products that were created were created in an +environment where you had either a lack of regulation or +regulators that were not properly adhering to regulations, +following the law, making others follow the law. + Mr. Bevins, could you just comment on this briefly? + Mr. Bivens. Yes, I think I agree with all of that. The idea +that especially Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were prime drivers +of the housing bubble just doesn't work when you look at the +evidence. + As the housing bubble gets under way in the early 2000s, as +home prices go through the roof, and as these exotic mortgages +come online, Fannie and Freddie hemorrhage market share. They +lose it to all of the private servicers. + They, unfortunately, start to try to get into the game a +little later in the decade, and they shouldn't have. That is +clear. But they were not--they were followers. They were +absolutely not leaders. And so, the idea that the housing +bubble can be laid at their feet, I think, is just wrongheaded. + Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Chairman Paul. I now yield 5 minutes to Congressman +Luetkemeyer from Missouri. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + A while ago, Dr. DiLorenzo, you talked about another bubble +coming. Can you elaborate on that just a little bit? + Mr. DiLorenzo. With all the so-called quantitative easing +that the Fed is engaging in, it is more of the same policy that +created the real estate bubble in the first place. And, at that +time, it reallocated a lot of capital into housing and housing- +related industries. And so, even if we are not seeing price +inflation, we have all this credit out there, the potential for +lending. And, of course, the banks aren't lending as much as a +lot of people would like to see them lend. + And so we can't really predict where the next bubble will +be, but it was in the stock market--before the housing bubble, +there was a stock market bubble. And the Fed responded to that +bubble with the policy of low interest rates that created the +housing bubble. And so I fear that we are going to have another +one because of the amount of money that is being put in +circulation is orders of magnitude greater than what the +Greenspan Fed did. + But no one can forecast or predict what industry it is +going to hit, and so I am afraid I can't help you there. But I +am pretty confident that we should be worried about it. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. What you are saying, though, is that, as a +result of the money supply, there will be another bubble, +because you are putting into the system some sort of an anomaly +that will cause something else to happen somewhere else, such +as-- + Mr. DiLorenzo. Yes. What happened with real estate is the +low interest rates made it much more profitable to invest in +long-term investments when interest rates go down. And so, all +that money and resources is poured into real estate especially, +and it ended up not being sustainable. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Do you have a best guess as to where it +may happen next? + Mr. DiLorenzo. We have some criteria. Like, one of the +reasons why I think it happened in real estate and it was such +a catastrophe was all these new products, new financial +products, and there were a lot of people who really were +confused by them. + And so, just as a general rule, in industries that are +relatively new, where there is uncertainty on the side of the +consumer, that is where the trouble can be. And so that might +lead to a lot of possibilities. But I can't--I don't have any +particular industry that I could--maybe Professor Vedder does. +I don't. + Mr. Vedder. I think economists who make predictions are +foolish. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Are there a lot of Fed economists around? + Mr. Vedder. A lot of failing economists? + Mr. Luetkemeyer. No. Aren't there a lot of economists at +the Fed? + Mr. Vedder. There are a lot, and there are a lot of +mistakes that are made. Dr. Bivens mentioned with great +admiration Christina Romer, whose most famous quote in modern +times was her quote early in 2009 when she said, ``If the +stimulus package passes, the unemployment rate will not go +above 8 percent.'' It is at 9 percent now and has been to 10 +percent. + And so, I agree with Tom that we have a ticking time bomb +out there, and exactly what the shape of the disaster will be I +don't know. We have these mammoth excess reserves at banks. + And Dr. Bivens is actually right, he is absolutely right, +we haven't had a huge amount of inflation now. And it is true +people aren't spending a lot of money now. Why aren't they +spending money? Is it because interest rates are too high? No. +It is because they are scared. They are just downright scared. +They are scared because, ``Oh, we don't know this Obamacare, +what it is going to do to us.'' We have had a regime change. +People are scared. We are not used to big changes all at once. +And because of that--but we have the potential for a disaster. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Okay. Very good. Thank you. + Dr. Bivens, you made a comment a while ago--you were +discussing Japan. And they have had many, many influxes of cash +into their economic system, QE2, 3, 4, 5, 6, whatever. And you +made the point that it was able, as a result of that, to sort +of help keep inflation low and interest rates low. + My concern is that their economy still is struggling. And +it has been that way for 15, 20 years. If QE2 is supposed to be +the end-all, be-all to help us create jobs and get our economy +going, how do you correlate those two? + Mr. Bivens. If you look at Japan, it pretty much had a lost +decade of the 1990s, and they were sort of riven with internal +debate about just how aggressive to get with monetary policy. +And they never actually did, sort of, the unconventional large- +scale asset purchases that the Fed has been doing. And-- + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Yes, but didn't they put a lot of money +into the system, though? + Mr. Bivens. They kept interest rates very low, yes. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. That is my point. My point is, if we go +along with the Fed's mindset here and policy of throwing more +money into the system and we look at Japan as an example, over +many years and on many QE2s or QE1s or whatever, and it didn't +really do what we are hoping that this QE2 over here is going +to do, what is the thought process that would lead one to +believe that ours is going to be different than theirs? + Mr. Bivens. It won't be different. They only saw a real +recovery between 2002 and 2008 when they started doing the +QE2s. Before that, they sat at zero, but they did no more. They +said, we can't do anything else unconventional, you just don't +do that. Everyone--not everyone--many people said, no, the +economy needs more. + When they finally started doing more on the monetary side, +they actually saw a pretty decent recovery during 2002 to 2008. +And then, of course, everybody, globally, went into the great +recession. + Mr. Luetkemeyer. Okay. I see my time is up. Thank you, Mr. +Chairman. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I want to yield 5 minutes now to Congresswoman Hayworth +from New York. + Dr. Hayworth. I yield my time at this time, Mr. Chairman. +Thank you. + Chairman Paul. Okay. Thank you. + I yield 5 minutes to Congressman Huizenga from Michigan. Is +he not here? + Okay. I yield 5 minutes to Congressman Schweikert from +Arizona. + Mr. Schweikert. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, committee members, +and witnesses. + I may be one of those who is a little less interested in +what is going on now or the last couple of years. I can grab a +financial paper and read that. What I am trying to get my head +around is a central bank and the monetary policy as we run it +as a country for the last, let's call it, 100 years. Does it +exacerbate the swings and, therefore, in many ways, unemploy +more people and make the troughs much deeper? + For any of you, if someone like myself wanted to sit and +read and get better educated, where in the literature do I find +the best scholarly, fairest, and most detailed papers? Let's +start from the left. + Mr. DiLorenzo. There are several treatises on the history +of money and banking. One of them is authored by Richard +Timberlake, who has taught economics at the University of +Georgia for many years. He is retired now. There is another one +by Murray Rothbard, ``A History of Money and Banking in the +United States.'' And those are both very good books. + And since you are a very busy Member of Congress, that +sounds like a tall order to begin with, but-- + Mr. Schweikert. One of the joys of being from Arizona is +that I have a 5-hour flight both ways. + Mr. DiLorenzo. Okay, those are two books I would pick up. + But, also, this weekend there is a conference at Wake +Forest University under the title, ``The Fed Was a Mistake.'' +And there is a professor from the University of Georgia named +George Selgin who is giving a presentation based on an academic +paper. And he has looked at the last hundred years of the Fed's +performance, the very question you are asking. And I can put +you in touch with Professor Selgin, if you really would like +to, for your next flight back to Arizona. + But he was actually at my university last week and gave +this presentation, a PowerPoint. And he looked at all the Fed's +obstensible goals--price stability, unemployment--and makes the +case that the Fed has, in general, failed, although it has not +been a dramatic failure, but it was a failure nevertheless to +stabilize prices and unemployment. + Mr. Schweikert. I appreciate it. I know I have only 5 +minutes, so I want to, sort of, drive through this. + Mr. Vedder. Congressman, there is a new history of the +Federal Reserve written by a very distinguished scholar, Allan +Meltzer of Carnegie Mellon University. It is up through the +1980s or the 1990s. And it is not a complete history, but it is +a second volume of a history. He is a very well-renowned +monetary scholar. I haven't read the book entirely, but I sat +in on a conversation with him and Chairman Volcker a couple of +weeks ago at AEI, and it strikes me that it would be a very +instructive kind of work, as well. + Mr. Schweikert. All right. + Mr. Bivens. Just quickly, spanning the spectrum of +ideology, ``A Monetary History of the United States,'' Milton +Friedman and Anna Schwartz. + Mr. Schweikert. Okay, which I actually have. + Mr. Bivens. ``Secrets of the Temple'' by William Greider. +What is that? + Mr. Schweikert. No, go on. + Mr. Bivens. And I would say an absolute classic and very +readable, ``Manias, Panics, and Crashes'' by Charles +Kindleberger, formerly of MIT. + Mr. Schweikert. All right. + Mr. Chairman, witnesses, when I see monetary expansion in +the way--let's just take the most current case scenario. And, +at the same time, I have been spending tremendous amounts of +time reading about the GSEs and the overhang and the mortgages +and all the nonperforming debt we have at so many different +levels. + Does this monetary policy end up creating a situation where +we are not taking nonperforming assets and either writing them +down or getting them off the books? And does this end up +creating a huge overhang here that this monetization makes it +so I can keep them on the books, basically sort of creating +sort of a flat line? + Mr. DiLorenzo. Yes, that is exactly what has to happen, the +liquidation of all of those bad assets and those bad +investments. Historically, that is how recessions end. The bust +period, as I said earlier, of the boom-and-bust cycles that we +have is really the recovery period where businesses become +stronger on the way out, at the end of the recession. + And the Fed seems to have been doing everything it can to +delay that process of the liquidation of these bad assets. And +I think that is a very bad idea. + Mr. Vedder. I am going to defer an answer on this because-- +I think Tom is probably right, but I haven't studied the +specifics of the nonperforming assets closely enough to make an +informed-- + Mr. Schweikert. All right. + Doctor? + Mr. Bivens. I don't think it is--I think it is true that +some writing down of bad assets is going to be part of a good +recovery. I have to say, though, I think the Fed's actions by +avoiding deflation, outright falling prices, is actually going +to make people climbing out of their debt burdens over the next +5 to 10 years easier. + If you have a mortgage that is fixed at $150,000, and every +other price in the economy starts plummeting around it, then +all of a sudden your mortgage payment has just gotten a lot +more onerous for you. And so I think, by avoiding deflation, it +is actually going to make the debt overhang less of an +impediment to recovery in the next 5 to 10 years. + Mr. Schweikert. Okay. + Mr. Chairman, how much time do I have? + Chairman Paul. I think your time has expired. + Mr. Schweikert. Oh. And I was just getting to the really +good questions. + Chairman Paul. If you hang around, you will get another 5 +minutes. + Mr. Schweikert. All right. Thank you. + Chairman Paul. I would like to yield 5 minutes now to +Congressman Renacci from Ohio. + Mr. Renacci. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + I have been a small-business owner for 28 years, and I +actually created jobs at the age of 24 with very little money +in the bank. But I did have the opportunity to have banks +willing to lend me money and the opportunity to create over +1,500 jobs in my career. + I want to ask all three gentlemen on the panel whether they +believe the new duties given to the Fed in the Dodd-Frank Wall +Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act will have an effect +on employment growth. Because I am a believer that the free- +market system will create jobs. I am a little concerned about +that. I wanted to hear all three of your opinions. + Mr. DiLorenzo. The Fed has a publication that has a title +something like, ``The Structure and Functions of the Federal +Reserve.'' And it lists, I think, at least 30 or 40 different +areas where it regulates different types of financial markets. + And for those of you who are businesspeople, you know that +there is a very big cost involved in that. As Professor Vedder +mentioned about the Dodd-Frank bill, it is not a free lunch. It +is very costly to banks to enforce the provisions of that bill, +and they are going to pass on some of the costs to their +customers. + And so, expanding the prerogatives of the Fed is going to +add more layers of regulation and make the banking business +that much more costly. There may be benefits along, but it is +going to make it more costly and more costly to consumers, as +well, and more burdensome for businesspeople like yourself, in +my view. + Mr. Vedder. The cause of unemployment is too high a price +for labor. When labor cost go up too much, employers hire fewer +workers. It is the law of demand. It is very simple, not very +complicated. I wrote a book about this, which a lot of people +have praised to the skies. I thought it was the simplest +concept in the world. + Dodd-Frank, other things being equal, does not lower the +cost of labor. If anything, it raises costs generally to +employers, making it difficult to employ workers. So the net +effect of a mechanism like Dodd-Frank is probably to reduce, +rather than increase, employment and, thus, increase +unemployment in the United States. + Mr. Bivens. I would say quickly, it is going to have little +effect on what happens to unemployment. + I will make two distinctions here. One, I have been mostly +talking about, sort of, monetary ease and interest rates and I +think that the Fed has mostly gotten it right, at least in +direction. It is true, I do think that the Fed and every other +institution in the 2000s had too light a regulatory touch. And +so I think booms and busts are caused by light regulatory +touches. + I think the way that Dodd-Frank empowers the Fed to +actually provide some tighter regulation, I think that is going +to be a good thing, reduce boom-and-bust cycles in the future. +And so I think it is an improvement. + Mr. Renacci. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back. + Chairman Paul. I thank you. + We will now go into a second round of questioning. + I would like to address this question to Dr. Bivens. This +has to do with the debt that we have and its relationship to +monetary policy. Even the Chairman of the Fed, Chairman +Bernanke, has indicated that he thinks debt and deficits are a +problem and has admonished the Congress to get their budget +under control. + Do you have similar concerns? Is there a limit to how much +debt we can have and how high these deficits should run? Or is +that of no concern at all when we are in the midst of a +recession? + Mr. Bivens. I absolutely have concerns over, sort of, the +long-run debt limits that are on the United States. And I think +we should definitely move to, sort of, long-run, closer budget +balance than is currently forecast. + I will say, it is not a concern of mine over the next, say, +2 years. To me, what the economy needs now is spending power, +support from both the fiscal and monetary side. Some moving in +the next couple of years to radically reduce deficits and debt +would be very counterproductive. + But, absolutely, in longer-run periods, as unemployment +returns to a tolerable level, that should absolutely be a +concern. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I would like to suggest to Dr. DiLorenzo and Dr. Vedder +that there is a connection between monetary policy and +deficits. Because if we didn't have the facilitator there, the +ability of the Fed to buy debt and manipulate interest rates, +wouldn't there be a self-mechanism where Congress would +literally be unable to spend the money because interest rates +would go up? And interest rates--of course nobody wants them +high and they are bad politics, but wouldn't that be a way of +holding a check on government? + And, really, it isn't just the Congress; it is the fact +that the monetary system there accommodates the Congress +because there is a lot of bipartisanship in the Congress. +Sometimes, there are big-government conservatives who like to +spend money, and sometimes, there are big-government liberals +who like to spend money, and there is too much bipartisanship. +They get together and they spend this money. And they figure, +if we can get away with it, we are just going to allow the Fed +to monetize this. + And, for a long time, they can get away with it. And they +have done this, especially since 1971, until they finally got +this huge bubble that finally burst, and we are in the midst of +this great recession. For those who are employed, it is a +depression. + But do you agree with that connection, that the Fed has +something to do with encouraging the Fed to act irresponsibly? + Mr. DiLorenzo. I would. I think you hit the nail on the +head. I would agree completely with that. + And, of course, when the Fed gets involved, it reduces the +perceived cost of government. If you raise taxes to pay for +government services, it is much more explicit and hits you in +the face; you get a bill. But when the Fed prints money and +expands the money supply, it has what economists call a +``fiscal illusion effect.'' And it makes it that much easier +for this bipartisanship to occur that you referred to. + Chairman Paul. Dr. Vedder? + Mr. Vedder. I agree with Dr. DiLorenzo and with your +analysis, Dr. Paul. And, indeed, in my statement, I was worried +I was talking a little bit too much about fiscal policy and +debt, but I was doing it for exactly the reasons you indicated. +I think there is a real connection. + And throughout the history of the Fed, even going back +before 1951, when the Fed was tied into the Treasury to keep +interest rates down during the war, the Fed just keeping buying +bonds and so forth. It was a deliberate policy to help the +government manage its fiscal affairs. The Fed accommodated it +by monetizing a lot of the debt. + This has been going on and on and on. And it will go on as +long as Congressmen have to be re-elected every 2 years and as +long as the Fed has some connection to the Federal Government. +It is inevitable that it will go on. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + This is a question for Dr. Bivens. This has to do with a +reference to what Dr. Vedder said earlier. He said that part of +the reason we go into recessions is because labor costs get too +high. Of course, nobody likes to hear that. + But if this is true--and I believe Keynes spoke to this at +one time, because labor costs get too high, but you can't go +and, say, cut your labor. You can't cut nominal costs. But he +argued that real costs could go down by inflation. And you +raise it and you lower the value of the dollar, so real cost +goes down. And that helps you get out of the recession. + Do you buy into that argument? Or how would you look at +that, on the need to get labor costs down? + Mr. Bivens. I actually don't buy into that argument. + The way I read Keynes is, sort of, as follows: that the +first shot fired against his idea, that the way to fight +recessions is to try to have the Fed and to have fiscal +policymakers add more support to the economy, the first shot +was, no, no, you just need to get the price of labor down. And +he said basically, one, it is hard to get the price of labor +down, even if all workers in the economy said, ``Yes, we all +agree to a 10 percent wage cut today, cut our wages,'' all that +would do is lead to a 10 percent fall in prices, as well. So +the real wage actually would not fall much. It is actually very +hard-- + Chairman Paul. Wouldn't that be good? Wouldn't that be +good, to see prices come down? + Mr. Bivens. No, because-- + Chairman Paul. It would help the consumer. + Mr. Bivens. I am sorry? + Chairman Paul. It would help the consumer, with prices +going--what is so bad about prices going down? + Mr. Bivens. Because their wages went down the exact same +amount, and so their purchasing power has not changed at all. + Chairman Paul. Yes, but-- + Mr. Bivens. What you would do is you would make the value +of their debt more onerous. Basically, by increasing the value +of debt, again, you have a $150,000 fixed mortgage and all of a +sudden your wage is 10 percent lower, all of a sudden you are +more constrained by your nominal debt payments. And that will +make the economy worse. + And so, Keynes is pretty clear, wage-cutting is absolutely +not the way to get out of a recession. + Chairman Paul. Okay. + I now will yield 5 minutes to Congressman Clay. + Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + And, Dr. Bivens, we were told by Dr. Vedder that private +markets handled mortgages and other lending for generations +successfully without Federal intervention. Again, the data +shows otherwise. + According to the Congressional Research Service, during the +years 1920 through 1945, the last period of time when the +Federal Government had a very small role in homeownership, +rates were only between 40 and 50 percent of homeownership +nationally. Now that rate, at a time when the Federal +Government is supposedly inappropriately involved, is 67 +percent. The homeownership rate was even higher within the last +few years, as high as 69 percent. + So I don't see how the numbers back up these claims about +supposed excessive, expansionary policies on home lending. Can +you help explain this error? + Mr. Bivens. I think my assessment, sort of, agrees with +yours, that I think the government support of homeownership +played a key role in having that increase a lot in the post-war +era. I am willing to quibble a bit that maybe some of the +homeownership rates we saw in 2006, 2007 were bubble-inflated. +But the trend is clear as day: With the introduction of Fannie +and Freddie, with government support for homeownership, those +rates rose pretty quickly. + Mr. Clay. Thank you for that response. + Do you think there is value in having the Fed maintain a +dual mandate for monetary policy? + Mr. Bivens. I do, and especially if the alternative is to +drop the full employment mandate. I think that would be a +disaster. + To my mind, if there is a criticism of the Fed over a +longer run, the last 30 years, it is that they have actually +allowed that part of their dual mandate, the full employment +part of it, to sort of go by the wayside and focused +excessively on the price stability part. + And so, a Fed that actually took that dual mandate +seriously, I think, would be a very good thing. + Mr. Clay. Do you think that if the Fed were operating with +a single price stability mandate, that its execution of +monetary policy since the onset of the financial crisis of +September of 2008 would have been materially different or would +have led to significantly different outcomes in the economy? + Mr. Bivens. It is a good question. I think where that +single mandate of price stability would really be a bad thing +is during expansions. + The irony here is that most people think the Fed have +something like a 1 to 2 percent inflation target, seems to be-- +they are pretty consistently missing that, on the low side, +these days. Inflation rates are coming in well below 1 percent. + So even if they only had a commitment to 1\1/2\ percent +inflation--forget the employment side--if that was their only +commitment, they should still loosen. And so that is how bad +the economy is today. Even if all they had was a pretty +conservative price target, they should still be providing all +the support they are and maybe even a little more. + Mr. Clay. Thank you for that response. + And, Mr. Chairman, I yield back the balance of my time. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I now yield 5 minutes to Mr. Huizenga from Michigan. + Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate that. + And my colleague from Missouri just, actually, started +going down a road that I wanted to explore a little bit. + Dr. Vedder, from the historical perspective, I think it +would be helpful to have a very brief explanation about the +dual mandate. How long has it been in place? Why was it really +implemented? + And then, moving on to all three of you, is the dual +mandate a proper mandate? I think Dr. Bivens was starting to +talk a little bit about that, but I would like to hear the +remainder of the panel's views on that. + Mr. Vedder. The dual mandate--when I think of the history +of this, I think first of the Employment Act of 1946, where the +government committed itself to a policy of encouraging full +employment. And even in that bill, price stability was +mentioned, and it was part of the so-called mandate. Again, it +was more a statement of intent rather than a prescriptive +statement. + The Humphrey-Hawkins bill, which I think was, what, 1977 or +something like that, was a more explicit widening of that +mandate and made much more explicit. + And all of this precedes, sort of--there was almost +implicit in some of this, a lot of this, as relates to what we +might call the ``Phillips curve'' idea, that if you have price +stability--can you have price stability and full employment? +That is the empirical issue. + We can have that discussion. I do not think that the +manipulation of prices in the long run impacts on employment, +period. I think it does in the short run. I have written a book +which indicates it does. There is a Phillips curve in the short +run sometimes, but in the long run--higher inflation, lower +unemployment. But in the long run, I don't see that that +relationship exists. + Mr. DiLorenzo. In terms of the price stability, we have +price indexes that go all the way back to the 1790s or even a +few years before that. And the price level in 1913, when the +Fed was created, was roughly the same as it was in 1790, with +some ups and downs. But ever since the Fed was created, the +price level is 22 times higher now. So when I hear the idea +that the Fed has a mandate to stabilize prices, it is almost +farcical. + And I don't think, overall, it has done a very good job in +stabilizing employment either. You can mandate that is the +Fed's job, but I think, historically, it hasn't done a very +good job in either one. + Mr. Bivens. Yes, in regards to that, I will say that I +would much rather have average economic growth and the +frequency of duration of recessions we have had post-1914 than +in the 150 years prior. Basically, some moderate rate of +inflation is the price you pay for having economic growth and +fighting recessions in a serious way. + Again, to the degree that there has been a problem with the +dual mandate over the past 25, 30 years, it has been that one- +half of it, the full employment commitment, has really been +sort of the neglected part. + Mr. Huizenga. So if I am hearing you, Dr. Bivens, you want +to see the dual mandate remain, correct? + Mr. Bivens. Yes. + Mr. Huizenga. Okay. + And I guess, the other two panelists, do you believe it is +appropriate for that language to remain in there as goals and +objectives? Dr. Vedder and Dr. DiLorenzo? + Mr. Vedder. I think we ought to repeal the Humphrey-Hawkins +Act, period, just do away with it. + Mr. DiLorenzo. I agree with that. We have mentioned +Christina Romer several times. One of her academic articles +revises some data and shows that the business cycle was +actually not more unstable in the pre-Fed era in the 19th +Century than it was after the pre-Fed era. So you can't even +make the case anymore, according to Christina Romer's research, +that the Fed has done anything to stabilize the business cycle +compared to the bad system we had, the admittedly bad, flawed +system we had before the Fed came into being. + Mr. Huizenga. Dr. Bivens, do you care to address Humphrey- +Hawkins at all or any of the other points? + Mr. Bivens. First, it was my understanding that Humphrey- +Hawkins was actually no longer in effect. Am I wrong on that? +Did it lapse in 2005 or 2006? + Mr. Huizenga. I wasn't here. + Mr. Bivens. Okay. Sorry. So I am not, you know--I think the +dual mandate should absolutely be part of what the Fed is +tasked to do. + Mr. Huizenga. Okay. + Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back my time. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I now yield 5 minutes to Congresswoman Maloney from New +York, who has joined us. + Mrs. Maloney. Thank you so much, Mr. Chairman, for this +hearing. + And I thank all the panelists for their thoughtful +testimony that they delivered to our offices. + I would like to ask Dr. Vedder to comment on some of the +facts that were raised in Dr. Bivens's testimony. In his +testimony, he cited a study estimating that the $600 billion in +Treasury asset purchases is likely to boost GDP by up to a full +percentage point, which translates into roughly 1 million full- +time jobs. + That same study also stated that the full effect of all +large-scale asset purchases undertaken by the Federal Reserve +probably supported nearly 3 million jobs and will have lowered +measured unemployment by 1.5 percentage points through the end +of 2012. Other economists and researchers have supported this +with similar studies and results. + And so my question to Dr. Vedder is, isn't this solid +research, solid evidence that sound monetary policy does help +create jobs? + Mr. Vedder. I haven't read the studies, to be honest, +Congresswoman. + But I will say this: Since the recession began in late +2007, the Fed has followed the most expansionary monetary +policy in, I think, its history in a situation like this. It +has created a trillion dollars in excess reserves. It has done +a whole variety of efforts and exertions to bail out companies +and so forth in distress. And yet, we have fewer people working +today than we did when this effort began. We have the worst +employment record of any major downturn since the Great +Depression. + And so I can't see any positive association between Federal +Reserve monetary policy and job creation based on the reading +of the evidence in a period when we have a 9 percent +unemployment rate and we have, what, 15 million--``X'' number +of people out of work. It is kind of hard to get warm and fuzzy +about the Fed's success rate with its monetary policy in recent +times. + Mrs. Maloney. May I ask unanimous consent to place this +study in the record? + Chairman Paul. Without objection, it is so ordered. + Mrs. Maloney. And also to state that Christina Romer and +others, other economists, including major economists, have +testified that the economic shocks that our country has +suffered are 3 times worse than the Great Depression. As the +daughter of parents who suffered through the Great Depression, +no matter how horrible this recession is or has been, it is +nothing like what our country went through in the Great +Depression. + So I would like to ask Dr. Bivens, Dr. Vedder mentioned +that he believes that there should be constitutional +constraints placed on the Federal Reserve's authority. Can you +comment on that? And do you agree? + Mr. Bivens. First, I would just like to reiterate your +point. It is bad out there in the U.S. economy; the great +recession is really bad. The shock to the private sector that +happened with the burst in the housing bubble is absolutely +enormous. Like you say, researchers in many places say it was +bigger than what led to, actually, the Great Depression. And I +think it was the aggressive response of policymakers across- +the-board that kept it from being so. + In terms of constitutional limits on the Fed, I would like +a lot more detail. If those limits would impede them from +fighting future recessions as aggressively as they fought this +one, I think that would be a very bad thing. + I think it is one thing to say this has been the most +aggressive response ever and we still have 9 percent +unemployment. It is kind of like, imagine a town that is +building a levee wall in response to a flood. You can say, ``It +is the biggest levee we ever built, but the water keeps coming +over it. We should stop. It is bigger than we have ever +built.'' You have to build a wall as big as the shock. + Mrs. Maloney. Okay. Thank you. + Last week, Chairman Bernanke gave a speech at the National +Press Club. I ask unanimous consent to place that speech in the +record. + Chairman Paul. Without objection, it is so ordered. + Mrs. Maloney. And he stated that, although economic growth +will probably increase this year, unemployment is expected to +remain above and inflation below the levels that policymakers +have judged to foster maximum employment and price stability. + Since the Fed's rate has been near zero since December +2008, the Fed has been using alternative tools to provide +additional monetary accommodation. Specifically, the Fed has +been purchasing longer-term securities on the open market, or +in common speech it has been called quantitative easing. And +the goal of this has been to put downward pressure directly on +longer-term interest rates. + Chairman Bernanke--and I want to ask the panelists if they +could respond to whether or not they agree with his statement. +He stated that, ``A wide range of market indicators supports +the view that the Federal Reserve's securities purchases have +been effective at easing financial conditions.'' + I would like the panel to comment on whether they agree or +disagree. I think it is an important question. + Mr. DiLorenzo. They have to have had an effect in some +industries, of course, because wherever the money goes to +first. But, obviously, it has had very little effect on overall +unemployment, since the unemployment rate remains stuck around +9 percent or more, depending on how it is measured. + So, yes, it has had some effect on some industries. That is +why the stock market is up, some of the big corporations have +done well. But unemployment is not being very successful. + Mrs. Maloney. Could you also comment on what would have +happened if we had not engaged in quantitative easing with the +Fed's fund rate close to zero? What would have happened? + Mr. DiLorenzo. Since you are, sort of, looking at me, it is +not a coincidence, I don't think, that we have had somewhat of +an explosion in government at all levels--the Fed printing +money, government spending, government debt, and we are stuck +at 9 percent unemployment or more. Because all of this diverts +resources in the direction of government-directed spending in +resource allocation away from the entrepreneurs and the +business owners and the consumers, who know a lot better what +to do with that money than government bureaucrats and +politicians do. + And so I think we would be much worse off--as we said +earlier before you came, Congresswoman, that we may be sowing +the seeds of another bubble with all this quantitative easing. + Mrs. Maloney. Dr. Bivens, would you comment briefly? + Mr. Bivens. Yes, very briefly. If we had not done the +quantitative easing, long-term interest rates would be higher, +and we would have less business investment and consumer +spending. + And I would just note, business investment has performed +very well for the past 5 or 6 quarters, growing at about 15 +percent at an annualized rate. So we would have less of that if +we had not done the quantitative easing. + Mrs. Maloney. My time has expired. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I now yield 5 minutes to Congressman Jones from North +Carolina. + Mr. Jones. Mr. Chairman, thank you again. + And I again want to start with an e-mail from my district +and then get to a question. + This is Mr. Gordon Hansen from New Bern, North Carolina: +``Thank you for requesting my opinion with regard to the +Federal Reserve. My initial reaction to the Fed's policy to +printing more money is, how is the Fed going to stop inflation? +Since the beginning of this century, standard of living has +decreased because fuel increased so rapidly, the middle-class +wages could not keep up, and no one seems to notice or care.'' + This is America talking, quite frankly. And we have been +elected by the people from all over this country to represent +their feelings and their needs in Washington, D.C. + I have great respect for each and every one of you. You are +very learned men, much more than I. + The frustration that I see back in my district and I feel +is that, when I was born in 1943--and thank you for recognizing +my birthday tomorrow--when I was born in 1943, this country was +in war and coming out of war. This country impressed the world +with its greatness after the war, of how we were in a position +where we were creating things, we were manufacturing things. + And that gets me to the point that I am one of the few +Republicans--I am opposed to any trade agreement at this time. +I am not adamantly opposed to trade agreements, but when you +are in a deep recession, which everybody has acknowledged, why +are we passing the Korean trade agreement so we can create +70,000 jobs, I believe has been said. I am trying to verify +that, by the way. I don't believe it. + But the point is, this country is a debtor nation. Now, we +can pump it up, from the Feds to everybody else can put money +out here. But, as everybody is saying, the people understand +what is happening. They fully understand what is happening. + So my point is this. My State of North Carolina, from 1999 +until 2009, lost 376,000 manufacturing jobs. What would have +happened, in your opinion--I have a two-part question--what +would have happened, in your opinion, if we had not passed +NAFTA, CAFTA, and all of these trade agreements that supposedly +were going to create more jobs for the American people? + I think greed is probably the most dangerous thing +affecting America. Greed will destroy an individual, it will +destroy a family, it will destroy a country. And my humble +opinion is that greed has put America in this position, not +only because of trade agreements. + But, in your learned minds, give me an example of nations +that at one time were economically strong and yet, because of +some decision such as free trade, that these nations--and maybe +it is not exactly the same comparison--but these nations, in my +opinion--at one time, Spain ruled the world. At one time, +France ruled the world. At one time, Rome ruled the world. At +one time, America was the dominant power. Now it is China. And +we are slaves to China. We owe them over $900 billion. + From an economic standpoint, where do you see America? Are +we at a point that America needs to understand that we cannot +come back to be a strong power in the world? Are we at a point +where, yes, we will have somewhat of a quality of lifestyle, +but it is never going to go back, it is not even going to come +close to going back to what it was? + I don't think you can continue to sell yourself out to +other nations and expect to be strong economically or +militarily. + Any response? + Mr. DiLorenzo. Sir, the countries you mentioned, the +Spanish empire and so forth, they essentially bankrupted +themselves with empire. And, in my view, we are a long way down +that road with our military empire all around the world, too. +And so I think that is a contributing factor. + And the only other thing I will say is, I am a free-market +economist, but I opposed NAFTA at the time because when I first +saw it, it was, like, a thousand pages of government +regulations. And I didn't think it really constituted free +trade at all, but government-managed trade. And I guess you +would you have to do a careful study of how it has been managed +over the past 15 years or so to really know its effects. But I +wouldn't blame the problems on free trade, because I don't +think NAFTA was a free-trade agreement, despite the words +``free trade.'' + Mr. Jones. Thank you. + Mr. Vedder. I more or less agree with Professor DiLorenzo. +I do believe in free trade as a concept. I think most +economists do. This is one thing economists of all persuasions +more or less agree with, but we do put a lot of provisions in +these bills that get far afield from the issue of trade. And I +think that is a source of concern. + As an economic historian, I would have to note that nations +have rises and falls in the way people work and what they do. +We had a rise in manufacturing in the 19th and early 20th +centuries because of what us economists say, we had a +comparative advantage in manufacturing. We have lost some of +that comparative advantage today. Some of it has to do with +government policies. Some of it has to do with other things +that have nothing do with what the U.S. Government does. + I don't personally worry too much about the loss of +manufacturing jobs per se. What I worry about is the loss of +jobs in totality, the productivity of labor in its totality, +and so forth. And that is, I think, a broader concern. + Mr. Bivens. You asked a very big question, so let me just +try to be very brief. + I think it is absolutely true that if we want different +results, if we want living standards to continue to grow at a +reasonable rate in the United States for the broad workforce, +we better start doing lots of things differently. And one of +those things we should do differently is our international +economic policy. + I am a little shocked to agree; I also did not like NAFTA. +I think we need to think about exchange rates very differently. +And so we better start doing things differently if we want to +continue to grow. + Mr. Jones. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + I will yield 5 minutes now to Mr. Green from Texas. + Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. + Let's talk for just a moment about causal connections as +opposed to coincidence. Last summer, when the American Recovery +and Reinvestment Act was at its zenith, when it was providing +maximum benefit, we also at that time saw the turnaround in +terms of a recovery in the economy. + Mr. Bivens, was that just coincidence or is there a causal +connection? + Mr. Bivens. I definitely believe there is a causal +connection. Like you say, the Recovery Act was providing a sort +of maximal boost to the U.S. economy at that point. There are a +lot of estimates that said, without the support provided by the +Recovery Act, we would have seen zero growth for about 3 or 4 +quarters even after the official recession ended. + Mr. Green. Let's move now to the FDIC. + Mr. DiLorenzo, do you, sir, believe that the FDIC serves a +meaningful purpose with its ability to wind down banks that are +failing? + Mr. DiLorenzo. With its ability to close down banks? + Mr. Green. That are failing. When they are failing, the +FDIC moves in, usually on a Friday, they wind down the bank, +and then on Monday there is a new bank that opens, perhaps +under the same name, or a new name, but they do reopen, and +they move the assets. And they have the ability to do this with +a premium that is paid by banks so as not to interrupt the +economy. + Do you agree with this? + Mr. DiLorenzo. I don't think we need a government +institution to do that. That could be handled by the courts, I +would think. But it is probably one of the least offensive +things the FDIC-- + Mr. Green. You would not have the FDIC, you would have the +courts deal with the banks and the runs that would be created +on banks? You would have multiple banks, as was the case when +we were starting the great recession, that were challenged, and +you would just simply let all of these banks go into +bankruptcy? Do you not see that by doing this we would have +runs, greater runs on banks that would create greater stress on +the economy? + Mr. DiLorenzo. I am not sure--before we had an FDIC, I am +not sure you could make the case that the bank runs were worse +throughout history. + Mr. Green. They were. Before we had the FDIC, we had the +Great Depression. + Mr. DiLorenzo. Yes, for a few short periods. But if you +look at the long stretch of history, I don't think--you would +have a much tougher time making that case. + Mr. Green. I would say to you that a few short periods that +devastate the economy to the extent that the Great Depression +did is something that would not go unnoticed. + Mr. Bivens, do you think the FDIC serves a meaningful +purpose? + Mr. Bivens. Absolutely, for the reasons you say. They make +people secure in their deposits, and so you don't see the runs. + Mr. Green. Mr. Vedder, do you think the FDIC serves a +meaningful purpose? + Mr. Vedder. I wrote my doctoral dissertation on the FDIC. I +think, generally, it has been one of the more successful +government agencies. I do think it needs, however-- + Mr. Green. Excuse me, since my time is limited. Thank you. +Let me just follow up with this. + Mr. Vedder. It needs-- + Mr. Green. You will get an opportunity. + Let me follow up with this. Given that you think it serves +a meaningful purpose--and I agree with you--let us then +conclude something else. Do you think that we should be able to +wind down these AIGs of the world when they can provide +systemic risk to the economy? Or should they just be allowed to +bring the economy down? + The AIGs of the world--you are familiar with AIG? + Mr. Vedder. What do you mean by ``wind them down?'' Why +don't we let them go into bankruptcy? What is wrong with +bankruptcy? + Mr. Green. Why not let the banks go into bankruptcy? That +is the point. You just said that the FDIC protects banks. If +you are going to prevent banks from going into bankruptcy, why +not try to salvage the economy and prevent the types of stress +that can be caused by having these institutions that create +systemic risk, by preventing them from just simply going into +bankruptcy and creating all of these problems for us? + The point I am making is, Dodd-Frank deals with that. If +you don't like Dodd-Frank, then you don't like a means by which +we deal with ``too-big-to-fail'' institutions. Most people +think that we need to do something about these institutions +that were labeled ``too-big-to-fail.'' Dodd-Frank addresses +this. Dodd-Frank addresses other aspects. + You mentioned credit cards. Do you think there ought to be +something called universal default? A lot of consumers are +sitting in here. Are you familiar with that term, ``universal +default?'' + Mr. Vedder. I am familiar with the term, yes. + Mr. Green. Are you familiar with it? Do you think we ought +to have universal default? + Mr. Vedder. I haven't--I don't have a position on that. + Mr. Green. I do. I don't think consumers ought to be in a +position such that, because they have problems in one place, +credit card companies can simply decide, we are going to +declare you in default with us because you had a problem +someplace else, especially in this economy. Dodd-Frank deals +with this. + Mr. Vedder. Does it deal with Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac? + Mr. Green. Now, let me ask you one more. I have one more +for you. I believe you are a gold standard person. Is that a +fair statement, based upon your comments and your writings? + Mr. Vedder. I think the gold standard--we did well when we +were on the gold standard. + Mr. Green. And if we return to it, if we return to the gold +standard, what would happen? + Mr. Vedder. Pardon? + Mr. Green. What would happen if we returned to the gold +standard? + Mr. Vedder. It would be very--the return to the gold +standard is not--if we did it and if the world did it, I think +we would be a better place. I think we would be a better place. +But I don't see it happening in the short term. + Mr. Green. Let's assume that you have made a prediction +that we would be in a better place. Is that a fair statement? + Mr. Vedder. Yes. + Mr. Green. Now, what did you say about people who make +predictions earlier? + Mr. Vedder. Economists are lousy predictors. + Mr. Green. What did you say about the people who make +predictions? + Mr. Vedder. So why are you sitting here listening to me, +Congressman? + Mr. Green. I am listening to you because you are here as a +person who merits some attention, given that you are before +Congress. + Now, tell me, what did you say about people who make +predictions? + Mr. Vedder. What did I say? + Mr. Green. Yes, sir. You don't recall? + Mr. Vedder. I said that some people, some economists make +bad predictions, and some of them make good predictions. + Mr. Green. You had an ``F'' word that you used. + Mr. Vedder. I did? + Mr. Green. Yes. + Mr. Vedder. I don't remember. + Mr. Green. I do. You said they were foolish. + Mr. Vedder. Foolish? + Mr. Green. Yes, sir. + Mr. Vedder. Oh, okay. + Mr. Green. All right. Thank you for your prediction. + Mr. Vedder. Okay. + Mr. Green. I yield back. + Chairman Paul. I yield myself 5 minutes for closing remarks +and anybody else who wants to have another question. + I do want to bring up the subject generally of QE2. There +is a strong disagreement between those who object to it and Dr. +Bivens, who thought that it really has helped a whole lot. And +I don't think we will resolve that. + But, that was part of the program of injecting $4 trillion +into the economy, with the argument that it has done very, very +little at all and, some of us believe, maybe harm in the long +run. But the $4 trillion, actually we can argue that it did +help prevent a depression for some people, mainly Wall Street +and the big bankers and some corporations. They were able to +benefit. And who came out on the short end? The people who lost +their jobs and lost their houses and lost their mortgages. So +the whole thing didn't work if you were trying to help the poor +people. I think you were destroying the poor people while it +was nothing more than corporate welfare--$4 trillion, and we +have very little to show for it. + But the question I want to address is, there is a little +bit of talk--I don't think it is serious--about unwinding this. +We bought up all the trash, all the worthless assets. And the +taxpayers own this now, and it is on the books. We can't fully +audit the Fed. We can't find out what they are doing. And now +they are talking about, maybe we ought to unwind this. That is, +we are going to sell that trash. Who is going to buy it? How do +we do it? And when do we do it? + Chairman Bernanke says it is not time yet, but he is really +cocky about this. He knows when it is, and he is going to do +it, and he is going to do it smoothly. And what did he say +about problems coming? His anticipation, his whole idea that +when a crisis comes and when there is a recession, I can take +care of it, I know how to inject money in just unlimited +amounts. And I tell you what, he did, unlimited amounts, the +largest ever. And the jury may be still out on how bad a +failure it is going to be, but the time will come. + But the question is, what are we going to do about +unwinding? Are they really serious? And what would that do to +employment? If they did it now--they are not going to dare do +it now, with unemployment rates, real unemployment rates up to +22 percent, because it would do that horrible thing of raising +interest rates. So that is not going to happen. + What they are going to do is continue to look at the CPI. +That is where Bernanke is going to get his signal. When the CPI +goes up and we have price inflation, that is when we have to +unwind. + And he is so overconfident about this. You talk about +predictions and braggadocio, ``I can take care of it.'' Like, +he didn't know it was coming, he would take care of it if it +came, and now he says, ``I know exactly when to turn it off.'' +I just think that is such dangerous talk. + By looking at the CPI, what does he do? He takes the CPI, +he excludes food and energy, and says, gee, CPI isn't going up, +and he has price stability. There is no more price stability in +this country when you look at what happens to the bond prices +and the housing prices and commodity prices. There is nothing. +What is this stuff about unwinding? + I would like a comment from each one of you on what is +going to happen, or if it happens, and what are the abilities +of truly unwinding this and really saving us from a calamity? + First, Dr. DiLorenzo. + Mr. DiLorenzo. Congressman, what you just said reminds me +of what Friedrich Hayek won the Nobel Prize for in 1974. It is +summarized in a book of his called, ``The Fatal Conceit.'' And +it is essentially a critique of this whole idea that one man or +one group or one committee could, sort of, essentially plan an +economy, whether it is by manipulating interest rates or the +price level or whatever else. And I see no reason why we +Americans are better at central planning today than the +Russians were in the 20th Century. + That is basically the mindset that you are talking about +when you are talking about Chairman Bernanke claiming to be +able to manipulate the economy in these ways. I don't see any +way out. If he had a smooth exit strategy, I assume he would be +taking it right now. And so I see nothing but bad things that +could possibly happen from winding down, as you say. + Chairman Paul. Dr. Vedder? + Mr. Vedder. To me, the supreme irony of all of what you +just said and what Professor DiLorenzo said is, why was the Fed +created in the first place? I think if you read the history of +the period, after the panic of 1907--the panic of 1907, there +was no central bank. And so, what happened were a bunch of +private bankers, led by J.P. Morgan, sort of organized an ad +hoc committee to sort of save banks and prevent them from +failing. And by the way, it achieved some success in doing +that. + But afterwards, people said we can't have a single +individual serve as sort of the guru to save our economy, like +J.P. Morgan. We have to create a central bank and decentralize +it into 12 banks and all, to keep the power diffuse. + And we moved away from that diffusion of power back to the +centralization of power. Now it is Bernanke. At least J.P. +Morgan had some skin in the game. He had some money in the +game. When the banks failed, he failed. What does Bernanke have +in the game? He gets his salary anyway and then goes off to +work for Goldman Sachs. + So I think that is it. And I have no idea how it is going +to be unwound. Because it is an historically unprecedented +situation, I can't predict. But I am uneasy. And that is why +markets are uneasy. And that is why prices--that is why we have +the problems we have. That is why bond prices are starting to +go up. That is why Moody's is starting to say, should we give +AAA bond rating to the U.S. Government securities? Things like +that. People are getting uneasy. + Chairman Paul. Maybe Dr. Bivens will be more optimistic. + Mr. Bivens. Slightly, yes. It is not a trivial challenge +about how this is all going to be unwound. But I will say just +two things quickly. + One, it is going to actually feel like a luxurious decision +if we can start unwinding this and the unemployment rate is +much lower. And so, to my mind, the proper focus now is on +providing maximal support to job growth in the economy, not +worrying so much about how this is unwound. + And two, I have to say, I am sure there will be mistakes +made as we do it. I am sure there will be some targets missed. +But he has actually--Ben Bernanke and the rest of the Fed has +laid out a strategy for how this will be unwound. They have +talked about the instruments they are going to use, the levers. +Is it going to work perfectly? Are they going to hit forecasts +to the decimal point? Absolutely not. But, to my mind, the fact +that they are focused much more on support and job growth in +the near term says very good things about what they are doing. + Chairman Paul. Thank you. + Mr. Clay, I yield to you for another 5 minutes. Or Mr. +Green. + Mr. Clay. Mr. Chairman, I will yield to Mr. Green. + Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I thank the ranking +member, as well. + I would close by reminding us that we have seen, I am sure +many of you, the movie, ``Back to the Future.'' Based upon what +I have heard today, there are some who would take us ``forward +to the past''--back to the past, or forward to the past, when +we didn't have a Fed, when we didn't have FDIC, when we did not +have VA, when we did not have many of the institutions that +have helped people move into the middle class. Home ownership, +30-year mortgages--these things have made a difference in the +lives of the American people. + And I would caution us, before we make decisions to +eliminate institutions that have served us well, perhaps we +should consider the unintended consequences of such a massive +decision. And I think we ought to proceed with a great degree +of caution when we say things like, we can live without the +Fed, without the FDIC. I am indicating VA; no one said it. But +when you are on this track, it appears to me that you may be +talking about the VA, as well. + Many of these institutions have served a good many middle- +class people well, and we ought to move with caution. + I thank you for the time, and I yield back. + Chairman Paul. The hearing is adjourned. + [Whereupon, at 12:15 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] + A P P E N D I X + + + + February 9, 2011 + +[GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] + + +